HOME

TheInfoList



OR:

In graph theory, the matching polytope of a given graph is a geometric object representing the possible matchings in the graph. It is a
convex polytope A convex polytope is a special case of a polytope, having the additional property that it is also a convex set contained in the n-dimensional Euclidean space \mathbb^n. Most texts. use the term "polytope" for a bounded convex polytope, and the wo ...
each of whose corners corresponds to a matching. It has great theoretical importance in the theory of matching.


Preliminaries


Incidence vectors and matrices

Let ''G'' = (''V'', ''E'') be a graph with ''n'' = , ''V'', nodes and ''m'' = , ''E'', edges. For every subset ''U'' of vertices, its ''incidence vector'' 1''U'' is a vector of size ''n'', in which element ''v'' is 1 if node v is in ''U'', and 0 otherwise. Similarly, for every subset ''F'' of edges, its incidence vector 1F is a vector of size ''m'', in which element ''e'' is 1 if edge ''e'' is in ''F,'' and 0 otherwise. For every node ''v'' in ''V'', the set of edges in ''E'' adjacent to ''v'' is denoted by ''E''(''v''). Therefore, each vector 1''E(v)'' is a 1-by-''m'' vector in which element ''e'' is 1 if edge ''e'' is adjacent to ''v,'' and 0 otherwise. The '' incidence matrix'' of the graph, denoted by AG, is an ''n''-by-''m'' matrix in which each row v is the incidence vector 1''E(V)''. In other words, each element ''v'',''e'' in the matrix is 1 if node ''v'' is adjacent to edge ''e'', and 0 otherwise. Below are three examples of incidence matrices: the triangle graph (a cycle of length 3), a square graph (a cycle of length 4), and the complete graph on 4 vertices.


Linear programs

For every subset ''F'' of edges, the dot product 1''E(v)'' · 1F represents the number of edges in ''F'' that are adjacent to ''v''. Therefore, the following statements are equivalent: * A subset ''F'' of edges represents a matching in ''G;'' * For every node ''v'' in ''V'': 1''E(v)'' · 1F ''≤ 1.'' * A''G'' · 1F ''≤ 1V.'' The cardinality of a set ''F'' of edges is the dot product 1''E'' ''·'' 1F ''.'' Therefore, a
maximum cardinality matching Maximum cardinality matching is a fundamental problem in graph theory. We are given a graph , and the goal is to find a matching containing as many edges as possible; that is, a maximum cardinality subset of the edges such that each vertex is ...
in ''G'' is given by the following integer linear program:
Maximize 1''E'' ''·'' x Subject to: x in ''m'' __________ A''G'' · x ''≤ 1V.''


Fractional matching polytope

The fractional matching polytope of a graph ''G'', denoted FMP(''G''), is the polytope defined by the relaxation of the above linear program, in which each ''x'' may be a fraction and not just an integer:
Maximize 1''E'' ''·'' x Subject to: x ≥ 0''E'' __________ A''G'' · x ''≤ 1V.''
This is a linear program. It has ''m'' "at-least-0" constraints and ''n'' "less-than-one" constraints. The set of its feasible solutions is a
convex polytope A convex polytope is a special case of a polytope, having the additional property that it is also a convex set contained in the n-dimensional Euclidean space \mathbb^n. Most texts. use the term "polytope" for a bounded convex polytope, and the wo ...
. Each point in this polytope is a
fractional matching In graph theory, a fractional matching is a generalization of a matching in which, intuitively, each vertex may be broken into fractions that are matched to different neighbor vertices. Definition Given a graph ''G'' = (''V'', ''E''), a fraction ...
. For example, in the triangle graph there are 3 edges, and the corresponding linear program has the following 6 constraints:
Maximize x1+x2+x3 Subject to: x1≥0, x2≥0, x3≥0''.'' __________ x1+x2≤1'', x2+x3≤1, x3+x1≤1.''
This set of inequalities represents a polytope in R3 - the 3-dimensional Euclidean space. The polytope has five corners ( extreme points). These are the points that attain equality in 3 out of the 6 defining inequalities. The corners are (0,0,0), (1,0,0), (0,1,0), (0,0,1), and (1/2,1/2,1/2). The first corner (0,0,0) represents the trivial (empty) matching. The next three corners (1,0,0), (0,1,0), (0,0,1) represent the three matchings of size 1. The fifth corner (1/2,1/2,1/2) does not represent a matching - it represents a
fractional matching In graph theory, a fractional matching is a generalization of a matching in which, intuitively, each vertex may be broken into fractions that are matched to different neighbor vertices. Definition Given a graph ''G'' = (''V'', ''E''), a fraction ...
in which each edge is "half in, half out". Note that this is the largest fractional matching in this graph - its weight is 3/2, in contrast to the three integral matchings whose size is only 1. As another example, in the 4-cycle there are 4 edges. The corresponding LP has 4+4=8 constraints. The FMP is a convex polytope in R4. The corners of this polytope are (0,0,0,0), (1,0,0,0), (0,1,0,0), (0,0,1,0), (0,0,0,1), (1,0,1,0), (0,1,0,1). Each of the last 2 corners represents matching of size 2, which is a maximum matching. Note that in this case all corners have integer coordinates.


Integral matching polytope

The integral matching polytope (usually called just the matching polytope) of a graph ''G'', denoted MP(''G''), is a polytope whose corners are the incidence vectors of the integral matchings in ''G.'' MP(''G'') is always contained in FMP(''G''). In the above examples: * The MP of the triangle graph is strictly contained in its FMP, since the MP does not contain the non-integral corner (1/2, 1/2, 1/2). * The MP of the 4-cycle graph is identical to its FMP, since all the corners of the FMP are integral.


The matching polytopes in a bipartite graph

The above example is a special case of the following general theorem:
G is a
bipartite graph In the mathematical field of graph theory, a bipartite graph (or bigraph) is a graph whose vertices can be divided into two disjoint and independent sets U and V, that is every edge connects a vertex in U to one in V. Vertex sets U and V are ...
if-and-only-if MP(''G'') = FMP(''G'') if-and-only-if all corners of FMP(''G'') have only integer coordinates.
This theorem can be proved in several ways.


Proof using matrices

When ''G'' is bipartite, its incidence matrix A''G'' is totally unimodular - every square submatrix of it has determinant 0, +1 or −1. The proof is by induction on ''k'' - the size of the submatrix (which we denote by ''K''). The base ''k'' = 1 follows from the definition of A''G'' - every element in it is either 0 or 1. For ''k''>1 there are several cases: * If ''K'' has a column consisting only of zeros, then det ''K'' = 0. * If ''K'' has a column with a single 1, then det ''K'' can be expanded about this column and it equals either +1 or -1 times a determinant of a (''k'' − 1) by (''k'' − 1) matrix, which by the induction assumption is 0 or +1 or −1. * Otherwise, each column in ''K'' has two 1s. Since the graph is bipartite, the rows can be partitioned into two subsets, such that in each column, one 1 is in the top subset and the other 1 is in the bottom subset. This means that the sum of the top subset and the sum of the bottom subset are both equal to 1''E'' minus a vector of , ''E'', ones. This means that the rows of ''K'' are linearly dependent, so det ''K'' = 0. As an example, in the 4-cycle (which is bipartite), the det A''G'' ''='' 1. In contrast, in the 3-cycle (which is not bipartite), det A''G'' = 2. Each corner of FMP(''G'') satisfies a set of ''m'' linearly-independent inequalities with equality. Therefore, to calculate the corner coordinates we have to solve a system of equations defined by a square submatrix of A''G''. By
Cramer's rule In linear algebra, Cramer's rule is an explicit formula for the solution of a system of linear equations with as many equations as unknowns, valid whenever the system has a unique solution. It expresses the solution in terms of the determinants o ...
, the solution is a rational number in which the denominator is the determinant of this submatrix. This determinant must by +1 or −1; therefore the solution is an integer vector. Therefore all corner coordinates are integers. By the ''n'' "less-than-one" constraints, the corner coordinates are either 0 or 1; therefore each corner is the incidence vector of an integral matching in ''G''. Hence FMP(''G'') = MP(''G'').


The facets of the matching polytope

A facet of a polytope is the set of its points which satisfy an essential defining inequality of the polytope with equality. If the polytope is ''d''-dimensional, then its facets are (''d'' − 1)-dimensional. For any graph ''G'', the facets of MP(''G'') are given by the following inequalities: * x ≥ 0''E'' * 1''E''(''v'') · x ≤ 1 (where v is a non-isolated vertex such that, if ''v'' has only one neighbor ''u'', then is a connected component of G, and if ''v'' has exactly two neighbors, then they are not adjacent). * 1''E''(''S'') · x ≤ (, ''S'', − 1)/2 (where ''S'' spans a 2-connected factor-critical subgraph.)


Perfect matching polytope

The perfect matching polytope of a graph ''G'', denoted PMP(''G''), is a polytope whose corners are the incidence vectors of the integral perfect matchings in ''G.{{Rp, 274'' Obviously, PMP(''G'') is contained in MP(''G''); In fact, PMP(G) is the face of MP(''G'') determined by the equality:
1''E'' ''·'' x = ''n''/2.


See also

*
Stable matching polytope In mathematics, economics, and computer science, the stable matching polytope or stable marriage polytope is a convex polytope derived from the solutions to an instance of the stable matching problem. Description The stable matching polytope is the ...


References


External links


The matching polytope, by Michael Goemans

The matching polytope, by Jan Vondrak

The matching polytope, by Vincent Jost
Matching (graph theory) Polytopes