Basic classical and neoclassical theory
According to Classical economics, classical and Neoclassical economics, neoclassical economic thought, firms in a perfectly competitive market are price takers (rather than price makers) because no firm can charge a price that is different from the Economic equilibrium, equilibrium price set within the entire industry's perfectly competitive market. Since a competitive market has many competing firms, a customer can easily buy Widget (economics), widgets from any of the competing firms. Because of this tight competition, competing firms in a market each have their own ''horizontal'' demand curve that is fixed at a single price established by market equilibrium for the entire industry as a whole. Each firm in a competitive market will have buyers for its product as long as the firm charges 'no more than' the single price. Since firms cannot control the activities of other firms that produce the same widget sold within the market, a firm that charges a price that is higher than the industry's market equilibrium price would lose ''all'' business; customers would simply respond by buying their widgets from other competing firms that charge the lower market equilibrium price. This makes deviation from the market equilibrium price impossible. Perfect competition is commonly characterized by an idealized situation in which all firms within the industry produce ''exactly'' comparable goods that are Substitute good#Perfect substitutes, perfect substitutes. With the exception of commodity markets, this idealized situation does not typically exist in many actual markets. However, in many cases, there exist similar products which are Marginal rate of substitution, easily interchangeable because they are close Substitute good, substitutes (for example, butter and margarine).Henderson, James M., and Richard E. Quandt, "Micro Economic Theory, A Mathematical Approach. 3rd Edition", New York: McGraw-Hill Book Company, 1980. Glenview, Illinois: Scott, Foresmand and Company, 1988. A significant rise in a product's price will tend to cause customers to switch from this good to a lower priced close substitute.Roger LeRoy Miller, "Intermediate Microeconomics Theory Issues Applications, Third Edition", New York: McGraw-Hill, Inc, 1982. See Reference to "Price Elasticity" as it relates to "substitutability", as well as the "Marginal Rate of Technical Substitution" In some cases, firms that produce differing but similar goods have similar production processes; this makes it relatively easy for these one-good firms to Marginal rate of technical substitution, switch their manufacturing processes to produce the other differing but similar good. This would be the case when the cost of changing the firm's manufacturing process to produce the similar good can be somewhat immaterial in relationship to the firm's overall profit and cost. Since consumers will tend to replace goods whose prices are high with cheaper close substitutes and the existence of close substitutes whose manufacturing processes are similar allows a firm producing a low-priced good to easily switch over to producing the other higher priced good, the competition model will still accurately explain why the existence of different similar goods form competitive forces that deny any single firm the ability to establish a monopoly in their product. This effect is observable in a high profit and production cost industry, such as the car industry, and other industries facing competition from imports.Drake Bennett, "BusinessWeek"Persistence
In the ''absence of'' Barrier to entry, barriers to entry and collusion in a market, the existence of a monopoly, and therefore monopoly profit, cannot persist in the long run. Normally, when economic profit exists within an Industry (economics), industry, economic agents rush to form new firms in the industry in an effort to obtain at least a portion of the existing economic profit. As new firms enter the industry, they increase the supply of the product available in the market, and these new firms are forced to charge a lower price to entice consumers to buy the additional supply these new firms are supplying (they compete for customers). Since consumers will flock toward the lowest price (in search of a bargain), older firms within the industry actually face losing their existing customers to the new firms entering the industry, and are therefore forced to lower their prices to match the lower prices set by the new firms. New firms will continue to enter the industry until the price of the product is lowered to the point that it is the same as the average economic cost of producing the product, and all of the economic profit disappears. When this happens, economic agents outside of the industry find no advantage to entering the industry, supply of the product stops increasing, and the price charged for the product stabilizes. Essentially, a competitive situation always leads to an equilibrium solution. Normally, a firm that introduces a brand new product can initially secure a monopoly for a short while. At this stage, the initial price the consumer must pay for the product is high, and the demand for, as well as the availability of the product in the market, will be limited. In the long run, however, when the profitability of the product is well established, the number of firms that produce this product will increase until the available supply of the product eventually becomes relatively large, the price of the product shrinks down to the level of the average economic cost of producing the product. When this finally occurs, all monopoly associated with producing and selling the product disappears, and the initial monopoly turns into a (perfectly) competitive industry. When consumers have full information about the prices available in the market and the quality of the products sold by the various firms, there cannot be a persistent monopolistic situation in the absence of barriers to entry and collusion.Steven M. Sheffrin, "Rational Expectations", New York: Cambridge University Press, 1987. John Black, "Oxford Dictionary of Economics", New York: Oxford University Press, 2003. Various barriers to entry include patent rights and monopolization of a natural resource needed to produce a product. The American firm Alcoa, Alcoa Aluminum is a historical example of a monopoly due to natural resource control; their control of "practically every source of bauxite in the United States" (bauxite is used to produce aluminum) was one key reason that "Alcoa was, for a long time, the sole producer of aluminum in the United States". A barrier to entry can exist in a market situation that is characterized by a combination of high fixed costs in Production (economics), production and a relatively small demand within the firm's product market. Since a high fixed cost will result in a higher product market unit costs at lower production levels, and lower unit costs at higher production levels, the combination of a small product market demand for the firm's product, and the high revenue levels the firm needs to cover the high fixed costs it faces, indicate this product market will be dominated by a single large firm that uses economies of scale to minimize both its unit cost and its product price.The combination of high fixed costs and a small product market Demand ensures any reduction in a firm's Market share will significantly raise its unit costs. If entry of additional firms into the industry indicates total Production (economics), industrial production increases, a decline in the price charged for the Product (business), product would have to occur in order to accommodate the Demand, sale of the additional quantity that is Production (economics), produced for the product market. Even a small rise in the number of firms within the industry can quickly cause a large drop in profitability because of the double-whammy of rising unit costs and a falling price. This would tend to discourage the entry of new firms into the industry.See: Bradley R. Chiller's "Essentials of Economics"(1991), pages 143–144,
Henderson and Quandt, Microeconomic Theory A Mathematical Approach, pages 193–195
New firms would be reticent to enter such a product market if an apparent slim economic profit can turn into an immediate economic loss for all firms upon a new entry. However, since the qualities of most economic markets make them Contestable market, contestable markets, there may be a greater magnitude of product differentiation within this overall market structure, making it similar to a monopolistic competition structure.Government intervention
Competition law, Antitrust (competition) laws were created to prevent powerful firms from using their economic power to artificially create the barriers to entry they need to protect their monopoly profits. This includes the use of predatory pricing toward smaller competitors. In the United States, Microsoft Corporation was initially convicted of breaking the antitrust laws and engaging in anti-competitive behavior in order to form one such barrier in ''United States v. Microsoft''; after a successful appeal on technical grounds, Microsoft agreed to a settlement with the Department of Justice in which they were faced with stringent oversight procedures and explicit requirements"United States of America, Plaintiff, v. Microsoft Corporation, Defendant", Final JudgementFootnotes
References
*Kahana, Nava and Katz, Eliakim. "Monopoly, Price Discrimination, and Rent-Seeking". ''Journal Public Choice''. 64:1 (January 1990). *Langbein, Laura and Wilson, Len. "Grounded Beefs: monopoly prices, Minority Business, and the price of Hamburgers at U.S. Airports". ''Public Administration Review''. 1994. *von Mises, Ludwig. "Monopoly Prices". ''Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics'' 1:2 (June 1998). *Edwin Mansfield, "Micro-Economics Theory & Applications, 3rd Edition", New York and London:W.W. Norton and Company, 1979. *Roger LeRoy Miller, "Intermediate Microeconomics Theory Issues Applications, Third Edition", New York: McGraw-Hill, Inc, 1982. *Henderson, James M., and Richard E. Quandt, "Micro Economic Theory, A Mathematical Approach. 3rd Edition", New York: McGraw-Hill Book Company, 1980. Glenview, Illinois: Scott, Foresmand and Company, 1988, *Binger, Brian R., and Elizabeth Hoffman. "Micro Economics with Calculus", Glenview, Illinois: Scott, Foresmand and Company, 1988. {{DEFAULTSORT:Monopoly Profit Market failure Monopoly (economics) Profit Renting