Financial economics is the branch of
economics
Economics () is a behavioral science that studies the Production (economics), production, distribution (economics), distribution, and Consumption (economics), consumption of goods and services.
Economics focuses on the behaviour and interac ...
characterized by a "concentration on monetary activities", in which "money of one type or another is likely to appear on ''both sides'' of a trade".
[ William F. Sharpe]
"Financial Economics"
, in
Its concern is thus the interrelation of financial variables, such as
share prices,
interest rate
An interest rate is the amount of interest due per period, as a proportion of the amount lent, deposited, or borrowed (called the principal sum). The total interest on an amount lent or borrowed depends on the principal sum, the interest rate, ...
s and
exchange rate
In finance, an exchange rate is the rate at which one currency will be exchanged for another currency. Currencies are most commonly national currencies, but may be sub-national as in the case of Hong Kong or supra-national as in the case of ...
s, as opposed to those concerning the
real economy.
It has two main areas of focus:
[ Merton H. Miller, (1999). The History of Finance: An Eyewitness Account, ''Journal of Portfolio Management''. Summer 1999.] asset pricing
In financial economics, asset pricing refers to a formal treatment and development of two interrelated Price, pricing principles, outlined below, together with the resultant models. There have been many models developed for different situations, ...
and
corporate finance
Corporate finance is an area of finance that deals with the sources of funding, and the capital structure of businesses, the actions that managers take to increase the Value investing, value of the firm to the shareholders, and the tools and analy ...
; the first being the perspective of providers of
capital, i.e. investors, and the second of users of capital.
It thus provides the theoretical underpinning for much of
finance
Finance refers to monetary resources and to the study and Academic discipline, discipline of money, currency, assets and Liability (financial accounting), liabilities. As a subject of study, is a field of Business administration, Business Admin ...
.
The subject is concerned with "the allocation and deployment of economic resources, both spatially and across time, in an uncertain environment".
[See Fama and Miller (1972), ''The Theory of Finance'', in Bibliography.] It therefore centers on decision making under uncertainty in the context of the financial markets, and the resultant
economic
An economy is an area of the Production (economics), production, Distribution (economics), distribution and trade, as well as Consumption (economics), consumption of Goods (economics), goods and Service (economics), services. In general, it is ...
and
financial models and principles, and is concerned with deriving testable or policy implications from acceptable assumptions.
It thus also includes a formal study of the
financial markets themselves, especially
market microstructure and
market regulation.
It is built on the foundations of
microeconomics
Microeconomics is a branch of economics that studies the behavior of individuals and Theory of the firm, firms in making decisions regarding the allocation of scarcity, scarce resources and the interactions among these individuals and firms. M ...
and
decision theory
Decision theory or the theory of rational choice is a branch of probability theory, probability, economics, and analytic philosophy that uses expected utility and probabilities, probability to model how individuals would behave Rationality, ratio ...
.
Financial econometrics is the branch of financial economics that uses
econometric techniques to parameterise the relationships identified.
Mathematical finance
Mathematical finance, also known as quantitative finance and financial mathematics, is a field of applied mathematics, concerned with mathematical modeling in the financial field.
In general, there exist two separate branches of finance that req ...
is related in that it will derive and extend the mathematical or numerical models suggested by financial economics.
Whereas financial economics has a primarily microeconomic focus,
monetary economics is primarily
macroeconomic in nature.
Underlying economics
Financial economics studies how
rational investors would apply
decision theory
Decision theory or the theory of rational choice is a branch of probability theory, probability, economics, and analytic philosophy that uses expected utility and probabilities, probability to model how individuals would behave Rationality, ratio ...
to
investment management
Investment management (sometimes referred to more generally as financial asset management) is the professional asset management of various Security (finance), securities, including shareholdings, Bond (finance), bonds, and other assets, such as r ...
. The subject is thus built on the foundations of
microeconomics
Microeconomics is a branch of economics that studies the behavior of individuals and Theory of the firm, firms in making decisions regarding the allocation of scarcity, scarce resources and the interactions among these individuals and firms. M ...
and derives several key results for the application of
decision making
In psychology, decision-making (also spelled decision making and decisionmaking) is regarded as the cognitive process resulting in the selection of a belief or a course of action among several possible alternative options. It could be either ra ...
under uncertainty to the
financial markets. The underlying economic logic yields the
fundamental theorem of asset pricing, which gives the conditions for
arbitrage-free asset pricing.
The various "fundamental" valuation formulae result directly.
Present value, expectation and utility
Underlying all of financial economics are the concepts of
present value
In economics and finance, present value (PV), also known as present discounted value (PDV), is the value of an expected income stream determined as of the date of valuation. The present value is usually less than the future value because money ha ...
and
expectation.
Calculating their present value,
in the first formula, allows the decision maker to aggregate the
cashflows (or other returns) to be produced by the asset in the future to a single value at the date in question, and to thus more readily compare two opportunities; this concept is then the starting point for financial decision making.
(Note that here, "
" represents a generic (or arbitrary)
discount rate applied to the cash flows, whereas in the valuation formulae, the
risk-free rate is applied once these have been "adjusted" for their riskiness; see below.)
An immediate extension is to combine probabilities with present value, leading to the
expected value criterion which sets asset value as a function of the sizes of the expected payouts and the probabilities of their occurrence,
and
respectively.
This decision method, however, fails to consider
risk aversion
In economics and finance, risk aversion is the tendency of people to prefer outcomes with low uncertainty to those outcomes with high uncertainty, even if the average outcome of the latter is equal to or higher in monetary value than the more c ...
. In other words, since individuals receive greater
utility from an extra dollar when they are poor and less utility when comparatively rich, the approach is therefore to "adjust" the weight assigned to the various outcomes, i.e. "states", correspondingly:
. See
indifference price. (Some investors may in fact be
risk seeking as opposed to
risk averse, but the same logic would apply.)
Choice under uncertainty here may then be defined as the maximization of
expected utility
The expected utility hypothesis is a foundational assumption in mathematical economics concerning decision making under uncertainty. It postulates that rational agents maximize utility, meaning the subjective desirability of their actions. Ratio ...
. More formally, the resulting
expected utility hypothesis states that, if certain axioms are satisfied, the
subjective value associated with a gamble by an individual is ''that individual''s
statistical expectation of the valuations of the outcomes of that gamble.
The impetus for these ideas arises from various inconsistencies observed under the expected value framework, such as the
St. Petersburg paradox and the
Ellsberg paradox.
Arbitrage-free pricing and equilibrium
The concepts of
arbitrage-free, "rational", pricing and equilibrium are then coupled
with the above to derive various of the "classical"
[See Rubinstein (2006), under "Bibliography".] (or
"neo-classical") financial economics models.
Rational pricing is the assumption that asset prices (and hence asset pricing models) will reflect the
arbitrage-free price of the asset, as any deviation from this price will be
arbitraged away: the
"law of one price". This assumption is useful in pricing fixed income securities, particularly bonds, and is fundamental to the pricing of derivative instruments.
Economic equilibrium
In economics, economic equilibrium is a situation in which the economic forces of supply and demand are balanced, meaning that economic variables will no longer change.
Market equilibrium in this case is a condition where a market price is es ...
is a state in which economic forces such as supply and demand are balanced, and in the absence of external influences these equilibrium values of economic variables will not change.
General equilibrium deals with the behavior of supply, demand, and prices in a whole economy with several or many interacting markets, by seeking to prove that a set of prices exists that will result in an overall equilibrium. (This is in contrast to partial equilibrium, which only analyzes single markets.)
The two concepts are linked as follows: where market prices are
complete and do not allow profitable arbitrage, i.e. they comprise an arbitrage-free market, then these prices are also said to constitute an "arbitrage equilibrium". Intuitively, this may be seen by considering that where an arbitrage opportunity does exist, then prices can be expected to change, and they are therefore not in equilibrium.
An arbitrage equilibrium is thus a precondition for a general economic equilibrium.
"Complete" here means that there is a price for every asset in every possible state of the world,
, and that the complete set of possible bets on future states-of-the-world can therefore be constructed with existing assets (assuming
no friction): essentially
solving simultaneously for ''n'' (risk-neutral) probabilities,
, given ''n'' prices. For a simplified example see , where the economy has only two possible states – up and down – and where
and
() are the two corresponding probabilities, and in turn, the derived distribution, or
"measure".
The formal derivation will proceed by arbitrage arguments.
[Freddy Delbaen and Walter Schachermayer. (2004)]
"What is... a Free Lunch?"
(pdf). Notices of the AMS 51 (5): 526–528 The analysis here is often undertaken to assume a ''
representative agent'',
essentially treating all market participants, "
agents", as identical (or, at least, assuming that they
act in such a way that the sum of their choices is equivalent to the decision of one individual) with the effect that
the problems are then mathematically tractable.
With this measure in place, the expected,
i.e. required, return of any security (or portfolio) will then equal the risk-free return, plus an "adjustment for risk",
i.e. a security-specific
risk premium, compensating for the extent to which its cashflows are unpredictable. All pricing models are then essentially variants of this, given specific assumptions or conditions.
This approach is consistent with
the above, but with the expectation based on "the market" (i.e. arbitrage-free, and, per the theorem, therefore in equilibrium) as opposed to individual preferences.
Continuing the example, in pricing a
derivative instrument, its forecasted cashflows in the abovementioned up- and down-states
and
, are multiplied through by
and
, and are then
discounted at the risk-free interest rate; per the second equation above. In pricing a "fundamental", underlying, instrument (in equilibrium), on the other hand, a risk-appropriate premium over risk-free is required in the discounting, essentially employing the first equation with
and
combined. This premium may be derived by the
CAPM (or extensions) as will be seen under .
The difference is explained as follows: By construction, the value of the derivative will (must) grow at the risk free rate, and, by arbitrage arguments, its value must then be discounted correspondingly; in the case of an option, this is achieved by "manufacturing" the instrument as a combination of the
underlying and a risk free "bond"; see (and below). Where the underlying is itself being priced, such "manufacturing" is of course not possible – the instrument being "fundamental", i.e. as opposed to "derivative" – and a premium is then required for risk.
(Correspondingly, mathematical finance separates into
two analytic regimes:
risk and portfolio management (generally) use
physical- (or actual or actuarial) probability, denoted by "P"; while derivatives pricing uses risk-neutral probability (or arbitrage-pricing probability), denoted by "Q".
In specific applications the lower case is used, as in the above equations.)
State prices
With the above relationship established, the further specialized
Arrow–Debreu model
In mathematical economics, the Arrow–Debreu model is a theoretical general equilibrium model. It posits that under certain economic assumptions (convex preferences, perfect competition, and demand independence), there must be a set of prices su ...
may be derived.
This result suggests that, under certain economic conditions, there must be a set of prices such that aggregate supplies will equal aggregate demands for every commodity in the economy.
The Arrow–Debreu model applies to economies with maximally
complete markets, in which there exists a market for every time period and forward prices for every commodity at all time periods.
A direct extension, then, is the concept of a
state price security, also called an Arrow–Debreu security, a contract that agrees to pay one unit of a
numeraire (a currency or a commodity) if a particular state occurs ("up" and "down" in the simplified example above) at a particular time in the future and pays zero numeraire in all the other states. The price of this security is the ''state price''
of this particular state of the world; the collection of these is also referred to as a "Risk Neutral Density".
In the above example, the state prices,
,
would equate to the present values of
and
: i.e. what one would pay today, respectively, for the up- and down-state securities; the
state price vector is the vector of state prices for all states. Applied to derivative valuation, the price today would simply be : the fourth formula (see above regarding the absence of a risk premium here). For a
continuous random variable indicating a continuum of possible states, the value is found by
integrating over the state price "density".
State prices find immediate application as a conceptual tool ("
contingent claim analysis");
but can also be applied to valuation problems.
[See de Matos, as well as Bossaerts and Ødegaard, under bibliography.] Given the pricing mechanism described, one can decompose the derivative value – true in fact for "every security"
– as a linear combination of its state-prices; i.e. back-solve for the state-prices corresponding to observed derivative prices.
These recovered state-prices can then be used for valuation of other instruments with exposure to the underlyer, or for other decision making relating to the underlyer itself.
Using the related
stochastic discount factor - SDF; also called the pricing kernel - the asset price is computed by "discounting" the future cash flow by the stochastic factor
, and then taking the expectation;
[See: David K. Backus (2015)]
Fundamentals of Asset Pricing
Stern NYU the third equation above. Essentially, this factor divides expected
utility at the relevant future period - a function of the possible asset values realized under each state - by the utility due to today's wealth, and is then also referred to as "the intertemporal
marginal rate of substitution".
Correspondingly, the SDF,
, may be thought of as the discounted value of Risk Aversion,
(The latter may be inferred via the ratio of risk neutral- to physical-probabilities,
See
Girsanov theorem and
Radon-Nikodym derivative.)
Resultant models
Applying the above economic concepts, we may then derive various
economic- and financial models and principles. As above, the two usual areas of focus are Asset Pricing and Corporate Finance, the first being the perspective of providers of capital, the second of users of capital. Here, and for (almost) all other financial economics models, the questions addressed are typically framed in terms of "time, uncertainty, options, and information",
as will be seen below.
* Time: money now is traded for money in the future.
* Uncertainty (or risk): The amount of money to be transferred in the future is uncertain.
*
Options: one party to the transaction can make a decision at a later time that will affect subsequent transfers of money.
*
Information
Information is an Abstraction, abstract concept that refers to something which has the power Communication, to inform. At the most fundamental level, it pertains to the Interpretation (philosophy), interpretation (perhaps Interpretation (log ...
: knowledge of the future can reduce, or possibly eliminate, the uncertainty associated with
future monetary value (FMV).
Applying this framework, with the above concepts, leads to the required models. This derivation begins with the assumption of "no uncertainty" and is then expanded to incorporate the other considerations.
(This division sometimes denoted "
deterministic" and "random",
or "
stochastic Stochastic (; ) is the property of being well-described by a random probability distribution. ''Stochasticity'' and ''randomness'' are technically distinct concepts: the former refers to a modeling approach, while the latter describes phenomena; i ...
".)
Certainty
The starting point here is "Investment under certainty", and usually framed in the context of a corporation.
The
Fisher separation theorem, asserts that the objective of the corporation will be the maximization of its present value, regardless of the preferences of its shareholders.
Related is the
Modigliani–Miller theorem, which shows that, under certain conditions, the value of a firm is unaffected by
how that firm is financed, and depends neither on its
dividend policy nor
its decision to raise capital by issuing stock or selling debt. The proof here proceeds using arbitrage arguments, and acts as a benchmark
for evaluating the effects of factors outside the model that do affect value.
The mechanism for determining (corporate) value is provided by
John Burr Williams' ''
The Theory of Investment Value'', which proposes that the value of an asset should be calculated using "evaluation by the rule of present worth". Thus, for a common stock, the
"intrinsic", long-term worth is the present value of its future net cashflows, in the form of
dividends; in
the corporate context, "
free cash flow" as aside. What remains to be determined is the appropriate discount rate. Later developments show that, "rationally", i.e. in the formal sense, the appropriate discount rate here will (should) depend on the asset's riskiness relative to the overall market, as opposed to its owners' preferences; see below.
Net present value (NPV) is the direct extension of these ideas typically applied to Corporate Finance decisioning. For other results, as well as specific models developed here, see the list of "Equity valuation" topics under .
Bond valuation, in that cashflows (
coupons and return of principal, or "
Face value") are deterministic, may proceed in the same fashion.
[See Luenberger's ''Investment Science'', under Bibliography.] An immediate extension,
Arbitrage-free bond pricing, discounts each cashflow at the market derived rate – i.e. at each coupon's corresponding
zero rate, and of equivalent credit worthiness – as opposed to an overall rate.
In many treatments bond valuation precedes
equity valuation, under which cashflows (dividends) are not "known" ''per se''. Williams and onward allow for forecasting as to these – based on
historic ratios or published
dividend policy – and cashflows are then treated as essentially deterministic; see below under .
For both stocks and bonds, "under certainty, with the focus on cash flows from securities over time," valuation based on a
term structure of interest rates is in fact consistent with arbitrage-free pricing.
Indeed, a corollary of
the above is that "
the law of one price implies the existence of a discount factor";
correspondingly, as formulated, .
Whereas these "certainty" results are all commonly employed under corporate finance, uncertainty is the focus of "asset pricing models" as follows.
Fisher's formulation of the theory here - developing
an intertemporal equilibrium model - underpins also
the below applications to uncertainty;
see for the development.
Uncertainty
}, the asset's correlated volatility relative to the overall market
.
For
"choice under uncertainty" the twin assumptions of rationality and
market efficiency, as more closely defined, lead to
modern portfolio theory
Modern portfolio theory (MPT), or mean-variance analysis, is a mathematical framework for assembling a portfolio of assets such that the expected return is maximized for a given level of risk. It is a formalization and extension of Diversificatio ...
(MPT) with its
capital asset pricing model (CAPM) – an ''equilibrium-based'' result – and to the
Black–Scholes–Merton theory (BSM; often, simply Black–Scholes) for
option pricing – an ''arbitrage-free'' result. As above, the (intuitive) link between these, is that the latter derivative prices are calculated such that they are arbitrage-free with respect to the more fundamental, equilibrium determined, securities prices; see .
Briefly, and intuitively – and consistent with above – the relationship between rationality and efficiency is as follows.
Given the ability to profit from
private information, self-interested traders are motivated to acquire and act on their private information. In doing so, traders contribute to more and more "correct", i.e. ''efficient'', prices: the
efficient-market hypothesis, or EMH. Thus, if prices of financial assets are (broadly) efficient, then deviations from these (equilibrium) values could not last for long. (See
earnings response coefficient.)
The EMH (implicitly) assumes that average expectations constitute an "optimal forecast", i.e. prices using all available information are identical to the ''best guess of the future'': the assumption of
rational expectations.
The EMH does allow that when faced with new information, some investors may overreact and some may underreact,
[ Mark Rubinstein (2001)]
"Rational Markets: Yes or No? The Affirmative Case"
'' Financial Analysts Journal'', May - Jun., 2001, Vol. 57, No. 3: 15-29
but what is required, however, is that investors' reactions follow a
normal distribution
In probability theory and statistics, a normal distribution or Gaussian distribution is a type of continuous probability distribution for a real-valued random variable. The general form of its probability density function is
f(x) = \frac ...
– so that the net effect on market prices cannot be reliably exploited
to make an abnormal profit.
In the competitive limit, then, market prices will reflect all available information and prices can only move in response to news:
the
random walk hypothesis.
This news, of course, could be "good" or "bad", minor or, less common, major; and these moves are then, correspondingly, normally distributed; with the price therefore following a log-normal distribution.
Under these conditions, investors can then be assumed to act rationally: their investment decision must be calculated or a loss is sure to follow;
correspondingly, where an arbitrage opportunity presents itself, then arbitrageurs will exploit it, reinforcing this equilibrium.
Here, as under the certainty-case above, the specific assumption as to pricing is that prices are calculated as the present value of expected future dividends,
[Christopher L. Culp and John H. Cochrane. (2003).]
"Equilibrium Asset Pricing and Discount Factors: Overview and Implications for Derivatives Valuation and Risk Management"
, in ''Modern Risk Management: A History''. Peter Field, ed. London: Risk Books, 2003.
as based on currently available information.
What is required though, is a theory for determining the appropriate discount rate, i.e. "required return", given this uncertainty: this is provided by the MPT and its CAPM. Relatedly, rationality – in the sense of arbitrage-exploitation – gives rise to Black–Scholes; option values here ultimately consistent with the CAPM.
In general, then, while portfolio theory studies how investors should balance risk and return when investing in many assets or securities, the CAPM is more focused, describing how, in equilibrium, markets set the prices of assets in relation to how risky they are.
This result will be independent of the investor's level of risk aversion and assumed
utility function
In economics, utility is a measure of a certain person's satisfaction from a certain state of the world. Over time, the term has been used with at least two meanings.
* In a Normative economics, normative context, utility refers to a goal or ob ...
, thus providing a readily determined discount rate for corporate finance decision makers
as above,
[ Jensen, Michael C. and Smith, Clifford W., "The Theory of Corporate Finance: A Historical Overview". In: ''The Modern Theory of Corporate Finance'', New York: McGraw-Hill Inc., pp. 2–20, 1984.] and for other investors.
The argument
proceeds as follows:
[See, e.g., Tim Bollerslev (2019)]
"Risk and Return in Equilibrium: The Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM)"
/ref>
If one can construct an efficient frontier – i.e. each combination of assets offering the best possible expected level of return for its level of risk, see diagram – then mean-variance efficient portfolios can be formed simply as a combination of holdings of the risk-free asset and the " market portfolio" (the Mutual fund separation theorem In Modern portfolio theory, portfolio theory, a mutual fund separation theorem, mutual fund theorem, or separation theorem is a theorem stating that, under certain conditions, any investor's optimal portfolio can be constructed by holding each of ce ...
), with the combinations here plotting as the capital market line, or CML.
Then, given this CML, the required return on a risky security will be independent of the investor's utility function
In economics, utility is a measure of a certain person's satisfaction from a certain state of the world. Over time, the term has been used with at least two meanings.
* In a Normative economics, normative context, utility refers to a goal or ob ...
, and solely determined by its covariance ("beta") with aggregate, i.e. market, risk.
This is because investors here can then maximize utility through leverage as opposed to stock selection; see Separation property (finance), and CML diagram aside.
As can be seen in the formula aside, this result is consistent with the preceding, equaling the riskless return plus an adjustment for risk.
A more modern, direct, derivation is as described at the bottom of this section; which can be generalized to derive other equilibrium-pricing models.
}
Black–Scholes provides a mathematical model of a financial market containing derivative
In mathematics, the derivative is a fundamental tool that quantifies the sensitivity to change of a function's output with respect to its input. The derivative of a function of a single variable at a chosen input value, when it exists, is t ...
instruments, and the resultant formula for the price of European-styled options.
The model is expressed as the Black–Scholes equation, a partial differential equation
In mathematics, a partial differential equation (PDE) is an equation which involves a multivariable function and one or more of its partial derivatives.
The function is often thought of as an "unknown" that solves the equation, similar to ho ...
describing the changing price of the option over time; it is derived assuming log-normal, geometric Brownian motion (see Brownian model of financial markets).
The key financial insight behind the model is that one can perfectly hedge the option by buying and selling the underlying asset in just the right way and consequently "eliminate risk", absenting the risk adjustment from the pricing (, the value, or price, of the option, grows at , the risk-free rate).
This hedge, in turn, implies that there is only one right price – in an arbitrage-free sense – for the option. And this price is returned by the Black–Scholes option pricing formula. (The formula, and hence the price, is consistent with the equation, as the formula is the solution to the equation.)
Since the formula is without reference to the share's expected return, Black–Scholes inheres risk neutrality; intuitively consistent with the "elimination of risk" here, and mathematically consistent with above. Relatedly, therefore, the pricing formula may also be derived directly via risk neutral expectation.
Itô's lemma provides the underlying mathematics, and, with Itô calculus more generally, remains fundamental in quantitative finance.
As implied by the Fundamental Theorem, the two major results are consistent.
Here, the Black-Scholes equation can alternatively be derived from the CAPM, and the price obtained from the Black–Scholes model is thus consistent with the assumptions of the CAPM.[Don M. Chance (2008)]
"Option Prices and Expected Returns"
[Emanuel Derman]
''A Scientific Approach to CAPM and Options Valuation''
The Black–Scholes theory, although built on Arbitrage-free pricing, is therefore consistent with the equilibrium based capital asset pricing.
Both models, in turn, are ultimately consistent with the Arrow–Debreu theory, and can be derived via state-pricing – essentially, by expanding the above fundamental equations – further explaining, and if required demonstrating, this consistency.[ Rubinstein, Mark. (2005). "Great Moments in Financial Economics: IV. The Fundamental Theorem (Part I)", ''Journal of Investment Management'', Vol. 3, No. 4, Fourth Quarter 2005; ]
~ (2006). Part II, Vol. 4, No. 1, First Quarter 2006. (See under "External links".)
Here, the CAPM is derived by linking , risk aversion, to overall market return, and setting the return on security as ; see .
The Black–Scholes formula is found, in the limit, by attaching a binomial probability to each of numerous possible spot-prices (i.e. states) and then rearranging for the terms corresponding to and , per the boxed description; see .
Extensions
More recent work further generalizes and extends these models. As regards asset pricing
In financial economics, asset pricing refers to a formal treatment and development of two interrelated Price, pricing principles, outlined below, together with the resultant models. There have been many models developed for different situations, ...
, developments in equilibrium-based pricing are discussed under "Portfolio theory" below, while "Derivative pricing" relates to risk-neutral, i.e. arbitrage-free, pricing. As regards the use of capital, "Corporate finance theory" relates, mainly, to the application of these models.
Portfolio theory
The majority of developments here relate to required return, i.e. pricing, extending the basic CAPM. Multi-factor models such as the Fama–French three-factor model and the Carhart four-factor model, propose factors other than market return as relevant in pricing. The intertemporal CAPM and consumption-based CAPM similarly extend the model. With intertemporal portfolio choice, the investor now repeatedly optimizes her portfolio; while the inclusion of consumption (in the economic sense) then incorporates all sources of wealth, and not just market-based investments, into the investor's calculation of required return.
Whereas the above extend the CAPM, the single-index model is a more simple model. It assumes, only, a correlation between security and market returns, without (numerous) other economic assumptions. It is useful in that it simplifies the estimation of correlation between securities, significantly reducing the inputs for building the correlation matrix required for portfolio optimization. The arbitrage pricing theory
In finance, arbitrage pricing theory (APT) is a multi-factor model for asset pricing which relates various macro-economic (systematic) risk variables to the pricing of financial assets. Proposed by economist Stephen Ross (economist), Stephen Ross i ...
(APT) similarly differs as regards its assumptions. APT "gives up the notion that there is one right portfolio for everyone in the world, and ...replaces it with an explanatory model of what drives asset returns." It returns the required (expected) return of a financial asset as a linear function of various macro-economic factors, and assumes that arbitrage should bring incorrectly priced assets back into line.
The linear factor model structure of the APT is used as the basis for many of the commercial risk systems employed by asset managers.
As regards portfolio optimization, the Black–Litterman model
departs from the original Markowitz model approach to constructing efficient portfolios. Black–Litterman starts with an equilibrium assumption, as for the latter, but this is then modified to take into account the "views" (i.e., the specific opinions about asset returns) of the investor in question to arrive at a bespoke asset allocation. Where factors additional to volatility are considered (kurtosis, skew...) then multiple-criteria decision analysis can be applied; here deriving a Pareto efficient portfolio. The universal portfolio algorithm applies information theory
Information theory is the mathematical study of the quantification (science), quantification, Data storage, storage, and telecommunications, communication of information. The field was established and formalized by Claude Shannon in the 1940s, ...
to asset selection, learning adaptively from historical data. Behavioral portfolio theory recognizes that investors have varied aims and create an investment portfolio that meets a broad range of goals. Copulas have lately been applied here; recently this is the case also for genetic algorithms and Machine learning, more generally[Bagnara, Matteo (2021). "Asset Pricing and Machine Learning: A Critical Review". ] (see below).
Derivative pricing
In pricing derivatives, the binomial options pricing model provides a discretized version of Black–Scholes, useful for the valuation of American styled options. Discretized models of this type are built – at least implicitly – using state-prices ( as above); relatedly, a large number of researchers have used options to extract state-prices for a variety of other applications in financial economics.[Don M. Chance (2008)]
"Option Prices and State Prices"
For path dependent derivatives, Monte Carlo methods for option pricing are employed; here the modelling is in continuous time, but similarly uses risk neutral expected value. Various other numeric techniques have also been developed. The theoretical framework too has been extended such that martingale pricing is now the standard approach.
Drawing on these techniques, models for various other underlyings and applications have also been developed, all based on the same logic (using " contingent claim analysis"). Real options valuation
Real options valuation, also often termed real options analysis,Adam Borison (Stanford University)''Real Options Analysis: Where are the Emperor's Clothes?''
(ROV or ROA) applies option (finance), option Valuation of options, valuation technique ...
allows that option holders can influence the option's underlying; models for employee stock option valuation explicitly assume non-rationality on the part of option holders; Credit derivatives allow that payment obligations or delivery requirements might not be honored. Exotic derivatives are now routinely valued. Multi-asset underlyers are handled via simulation or copula based analysis.
Similarly, the various short-rate models allow for an extension of these techniques to fixed income- and interest rate derivatives. (The Vasicek and CIR models are equilibrium-based, while Ho–Lee and subsequent models are based on arbitrage-free pricing.) The more general HJM Framework describes the dynamics of the full forward-rate curve – as opposed to working with short rates – and is then more widely applied. The valuation of the underlying instrument – additional to its derivatives – is relatedly extended, particularly for hybrid securities, where credit risk is combined with uncertainty re future rates; see and .
Following the Crash of 1987, equity options traded in American markets began to exhibit what is known as a " volatility smile"; that is, for a given expiration, options whose strike price differs substantially from the underlying asset's price command higher prices, and thus implied volatilities, than what is suggested by BSM. (The pattern differs across various markets.) Modelling the volatility smile is an active area of research, and developments here – as well as implications re the standard theory – are discussed in the next section.
After the 2008 financial crisis
The 2008 financial crisis, also known as the global financial crisis (GFC), was a major worldwide financial crisis centered in the United States. The causes of the 2008 crisis included excessive speculation on housing values by both homeowners ...
, a further development:[Didier Kouokap Youmbi (2017).]
Derivatives Pricing after the 2007-2008 Crisis: How the Crisis Changed the Pricing Approach
. Bank of England
The Bank of England is the central bank of the United Kingdom and the model on which most modern central banks have been based. Established in 1694 to act as the Kingdom of England, English Government's banker and debt manager, and still one ...
– Prudential Regulation Authority as outlined, ( over the counter) derivative pricing had relied on the BSM risk neutral pricing framework, under the assumptions of funding at the risk free rate and the ability to perfectly replicate cashflows so as to fully hedge. This, in turn, is built on the assumption of a credit-risk-free environment – called into question during the crisis.
Addressing this, therefore, issues such as counterparty credit risk, funding costs and costs of capital are now additionally considered when pricing, and a credit valuation adjustment, or CVA – and potentially other ''valuation adjustments'', collectively xVA – is generally added to the risk-neutral derivative value.
The standard economic arguments can be extended to incorporate these various adjustments.[John C. Hull and Alan White (2014)]
Collateral and Credit Issues in Derivatives Pricing
Rotman School of Management Working Paper No. 2212953
A related, and perhaps more fundamental change, is that discounting is now on the Overnight Index Swap (OIS) curve, as opposed to LIBOR as used previously. This is because post-crisis, the overnight rate is considered a better proxy for the "risk-free rate". (Also, practically, the interest paid on cash collateral is usually the overnight rate; OIS discounting is then, sometimes, referred to as " CSA discounting".) Swap pricing – and, therefore, yield curve construction – is further modified: previously, swaps were valued off a single "self discounting" interest rate curve; whereas post crisis, to accommodate OIS discounting, valuation is now under a " multi-curve framework" where "forecast curves" are constructed for each floating-leg LIBOR tenor, with discounting on the ''common'' OIS curve.
Corporate finance theory
Mirroring the above developments, corporate finance valuations and decisioning no longer need assume "certainty".
Monte Carlo methods in finance allow financial analysts to construct "stochastic Stochastic (; ) is the property of being well-described by a random probability distribution. ''Stochasticity'' and ''randomness'' are technically distinct concepts: the former refers to a modeling approach, while the latter describes phenomena; i ...
" or probabilistic corporate finance models, as opposed to the traditional static and deterministic models; see .
Relatedly, Real Options theory allows for owner – i.e. managerial – actions that impact underlying value: by incorporating option pricing logic, these actions are then applied to a distribution of future outcomes, changing with time, which then determine the "project's" valuation today.
More traditionally, decision tree
A decision tree is a decision support system, decision support recursive partitioning structure that uses a Tree (graph theory), tree-like Causal model, model of decisions and their possible consequences, including probability, chance event ou ...
s – which are complementary – have been used to evaluate projects, by incorporating in the valuation (all) possible events (or states) and consequent management decisions;[ Aswath Damodaran (2007)]
"Probabilistic Approaches: Scenario Analysis, Decision Trees and Simulations"
In ''Strategic Risk Taking: A Framework for Risk Management''. Prentice Hall. the correct discount rate here reflecting each decision-point's "non-diversifiable risk looking forward."
Related to this, is the treatment of forecasted cashflows in equity valuation. In many cases, following Williams above, the average (or most likely) cash-flows were discounted, as opposed to a theoretically correct state-by-state treatment under uncertainty; see comments under Financial modeling § Accounting.
In more modern treatments, then, it is the ''expected'' cashflows (in the mathematical sense: ) combined into an overall value per forecast period which are discounted.
["Capital Budgeting Applications and Pitfalls"](_blank)
. Ch 13 in Ivo Welch (2017). ''Corporate Finance'': 4th Edition
And using the CAPM – or extensions – the discounting here is at the risk-free rate plus a premium linked to the uncertainty of the entity or project cash flows
(essentially, and combined).
Other developments here include agency theory, which analyses the difficulties in motivating corporate management (the "agent"; in a different sense to the above) to act in the best interests of shareholders (the "principal"), rather than in their own interests; here emphasizing the issues interrelated with capital structure.
Clean surplus accounting and the related residual income valuation provide a model that returns price as a function of earnings, expected returns, and change in book value, as opposed to dividends. This approach, to some extent, arises due to the implicit contradiction of seeing value as a function of dividends, while also holding that dividend policy cannot influence value per Modigliani and Miller's " Irrelevance principle"; see .
"Corporate finance" as a discipline more generally, building on Fisher above, relates to the long term objective of maximizing the value of the firm - and its return to shareholders - and thus also incorporates the areas of capital structure and dividend policy.
Extensions of the theory here then also consider these latter, as follows:
(i) optimization re capitalization structure, and theories here as to corporate choices and behavior: Capital structure substitution theory, Pecking order theory, Market timing hypothesis, Trade-off theory;
(ii) considerations and analysis re dividend policy, additional to - and sometimes contrasting with - Modigliani-Miller, include:
the Walter model, Lintner model, Residuals theory and signaling hypothesis, as well as discussion re the observed clientele effect and dividend puzzle.
As described, the typical application of real options is to capital budgeting type problems.
However, here, they are also applied to problems of capital structure and dividend policy, and to the related design of corporate securities;
[Kenneth D. Garbade (2001). ''Pricing Corporate Securities as Contingent Claims.'' ]MIT Press
The MIT Press is the university press of the Massachusetts Institute of Technology (MIT), a private research university in Cambridge, Massachusetts. The MIT Press publishes a number of academic journals and has been a pioneer in the Open Ac ...
.
and since stockholder and bondholders have different objective functions, in the analysis of the related agency problems.
In all of these cases, state-prices can provide the market-implied information relating to the corporate, as above, which is then applied to the analysis. For example, convertible bonds can (must) be priced consistent with the (recovered) state-prices of the corporate's equity.[See Kruschwitz and Löffler under Bibliography.]
Financial markets
The discipline, as outlined, also includes a formal study of financial markets. Of interest especially are market regulation and market microstructure, and their relationship to price efficiency.
Regulatory economics studies, in general, the economics of regulation. In the context of finance, it will address the impact of financial regulation on the functioning of markets and the efficiency of prices, while also weighing the corresponding increases in market confidence and financial stability
Financial stability is the absence of system-wide episodes in which a financial crisis occurs and is characterised as an economy with Volatility (finance), low volatility. It also involves financial systems' stress-resilience being able to cope wi ...
.
Research here considers how, and to what extent, regulations relating to disclosure ( earnings guidance, annual report
An annual report is a comprehensive report on a company's activities throughout the preceding year. Annual reports are intended to give shareholders and other interested people information about the company's activities and financial performance. ...
s), insider trading, and short-selling will impact price efficiency, the cost of equity, and market liquidity
In business, economics or investment, market liquidity is a market's feature whereby an individual or firm can quickly purchase or sell an asset without causing a drastic change in the asset's price. Liquidity involves the trade-off between the ...
.
Market microstructure is concerned with the details of how exchange occurs in markets
(with Walrasian-, matching-, Fisher-, and
Arrow-Debreu markets as prototypes),
and "analyzes how specific trading mechanisms affect the price formation process", examining the ways in which the processes of a market affect determinants of transaction costs, prices, quotes, volume, and trading behavior.
It has been used, for example, in providing explanations for long-standing exchange rate puzzles, and for the equity premium puzzle.
In contrast to the above classical approach, models here explicitly allow for (testing the impact of) market frictions and other imperfections;
see also market design.
For both regulation and microstructure, and generally, agent-based models can be developed to examine any impact due to a change in structure or policy - or to make inferences re market dynamics - by testing these in an artificial financial market, or AFM.
This approach, essentially simulated trade between numerous agents, "typically uses artificial intelligence
Artificial intelligence (AI) is the capability of computer, computational systems to perform tasks typically associated with human intelligence, such as learning, reasoning, problem-solving, perception, and decision-making. It is a field of re ...
technologies ften genetic algorithms and Artificial neural network">neural nets">genetic algorithms">ften and Artificial neural network">neural netsto represent the adaptive market hypothesis">adaptive behaviour of market participants".[Katalin Boer, Arie De Bruin, Uzay Kaymak (2005)]
"On the Design of Artificial Stock Markets"
''Research In Management'' ERIM Report Series
These Microfoundations">'bottom-up' models "start from first principals of agent behavior",[LeBaron, B. (2002)]
"Building the Santa Fe artificial stock market"
'' Physica A'', 1, 20. with participants modifying their trading strategies having learned over time, and "are able to describe macro features [i.e. stylized fact">Physica (journal)">Physica A'', 1, 20. with participants modifying their trading strategies having learned over time, and "are able to describe macro features [i.e. stylized facts] Emergence#Economics, emerging from a soup of individual interacting strategies".
Agent-based models depart further from the classical approach — the
representative agent, as outlined — in that they introduce
heterogeneity into the environment (thereby addressing, also, the
aggregation problem).
More recent research focuses on the potential impact of
Machine Learning
Machine learning (ML) is a field of study in artificial intelligence concerned with the development and study of Computational statistics, statistical algorithms that can learn from data and generalise to unseen data, and thus perform Task ( ...
on market functioning and efficiency.
As these methods become more prevalent in financial markets, economists would expect greater
information acquisition and improved price efficiency.
[Barbopoulos, Leonidas G. ''et al''. (2023) "Market Efficiency When Machines Access Information". NYU Stern School of Business. ]
In fact, an apparent rejection of market efficiency (see
below) might simply represent "the unsurprising consequence of investors not having precise knowledge of the parameters of a data-generating process that involves thousands of predictor variables".
At the same time, it is acknowledged that a potential downside of these methods, in this context, is their lack of
interpretability "which translates into difficulties in attaching economic meaning to the results found."
Challenges and criticism
As above, there is a very close link between:
the
random walk hypothesis, with the associated belief that price changes should follow a
normal distribution
In probability theory and statistics, a normal distribution or Gaussian distribution is a type of continuous probability distribution for a real-valued random variable. The general form of its probability density function is
f(x) = \frac ...
, on the one hand;
and market efficiency and
rational expectations, on the other.
Wide departures from these are commonly observed, and there are thus, respectively, two main sets of challenges.
Departures from normality
As discussed, the assumptions that market prices follow a
random walk and that asset returns are normally distributed are fundamental. Empirical evidence, however, suggests that these assumptions may not hold, and that in practice, traders, analysts
and risk managers frequently modify the "standard models" (see
kurtosis risk,
skewness risk
Skewness risk in forecasting models utilized in the financial field is the risk that results when observations are not spread symmetrically around an average value, but instead have a skewed distribution. As a result, the mean and the median can ...
,
long tail,
model risk).
In fact,
Benoit Mandelbrot had discovered already in the 1960s
that changes in financial prices do not follow a
normal distribution
In probability theory and statistics, a normal distribution or Gaussian distribution is a type of continuous probability distribution for a real-valued random variable. The general form of its probability density function is
f(x) = \frac ...
, the basis for much option pricing theory, although this observation was slow to find its way into mainstream financial economics.
Financial models with long-tailed distributions and volatility clustering have been introduced to overcome problems with the realism of the above "classical" financial models; while
jump diffusion models allow for (option) pricing incorporating
"jumps" in the
spot price.
Risk managers, similarly, complement (or substitute) the standard
value at risk models with
historical simulations,
mixture models,
principal component analysis,
extreme value theory, as well as models for
volatility clustering.
For further discussion see , and . Portfolio managers, likewise, have modified their optimization criteria and algorithms; see above.
Closely related is the
volatility smile, where, as above,
implied volatility – the volatility corresponding to the BSM price – is observed to ''differ'' as a function of
strike price (i.e.
moneyness), true only if the price-change distribution is non-normal, unlike that assumed by BSM (i.e.
and
above). The term structure of volatility describes how (implied) volatility differs for related options with different maturities. An implied volatility surface is then a three-dimensional surface plot of volatility smile and term structure. These empirical phenomena negate the assumption of constant volatility – and
log-normality – upon which Black–Scholes is built.
Within institutions, the function of Black–Scholes is now, largely, to ''communicate'' prices via implied volatilities, much like bond prices are communicated via
YTM; see .
In consequence traders (
and risk managers) now, instead, use "smile-consistent" models, firstly, when valuing derivatives not directly mapped to the surface, facilitating the pricing of other, i.e. non-quoted, strike/maturity combinations, or of non-European derivatives, and generally for hedging purposes.
The two main approaches are
local volatility and
stochastic volatility. The first returns the volatility which is "local" to each spot-time point of the
finite difference- or
simulation-based valuation; i.e. as opposed to implied volatility, which holds overall. In this way calculated prices – and numeric structures – are market-consistent in an arbitrage-free sense. The second approach assumes that the volatility of the underlying price is a stochastic process rather than a constant. Models here are first
calibrated to observed prices, and are then applied to the valuation or hedging in question; the most common are
Heston,
SABR and
CEV. This approach addresses certain problems identified with hedging under local volatility.
Related to local volatility are the
lattice-based
implied-binomial and
-trinomial trees – essentially a discretization of the approach – which are similarly, but less commonly,
used for pricing; these are built on state-prices recovered from the surface.
Edgeworth binomial trees allow for a specified (i.e. non-Gaussian)
skew and
kurtosis in the spot price; priced here, options with differing strikes will return differing implied volatilities, and the tree can be calibrated to the smile as required.
Similarly purposed (and derived)
closed-form models were also developed.
As discussed, additional to assuming log-normality in returns, "classical" BSM-type models also (implicitly) assume the existence of a credit-risk-free environment, where one can perfectly replicate cashflows so as to fully hedge, and then discount at "the" risk-free-rate.
And therefore, post crisis, the various x-value adjustments must be employed, effectively correcting the risk-neutral value for
counterparty- and
funding-related risk.
These xVA are ''additional'' to any smile or surface effect: with the surface built on price data for fully-collateralized positions, there is therefore no "
double counting" of credit risk (etc.) when appending xVA. (Were this not the case, then each counterparty would have its own surface...)
As mentioned at top, mathematical finance (and particularly
financial engineering) is more concerned with mathematical consistency (and market realities) than compatibility with economic theory, and the above "extreme event" approaches, smile-consistent modeling, and valuation adjustments should then be seen in this light. Recognizing this, critics of financial economics - especially vocal since the
2008 financial crisis
The 2008 financial crisis, also known as the global financial crisis (GFC), was a major worldwide financial crisis centered in the United States. The causes of the 2008 crisis included excessive speculation on housing values by both homeowners ...
- suggest that instead, the theory needs revisiting almost entirely:
Departures from rationality
As seen, a common assumption is that financial decision makers act rationally; see
Homo economicus. Recently, however, researchers in
experimental economics and
experimental finance have challenged this assumption
empirically. These assumptions are also challenged
theoretically, by
behavioral finance, a discipline primarily concerned with the limits to rationality of economic agents.
For related criticisms re corporate finance theory vs its practice see:.
Various persistent
market anomalies have also been documented as consistent with and complementary to price or return distortions – e.g.
size premiums – which appear to contradict the
efficient-market hypothesis. Within these market anomalies,
calendar effects are the most commonly referenced group.
Related to these are various of the
economic puzzles, concerning phenomena similarly contradicting the theory. The ''
equity premium puzzle'', as one example, arises in that the difference between the observed returns on stocks as compared to government bonds is consistently higher than the
risk premium rational equity investors should demand, an "
abnormal return". For further context see
Random walk hypothesis § A non-random walk hypothesis, and sidebar for specific instances.
More generally, and, again, particularly following the
2008 financial crisis
The 2008 financial crisis, also known as the global financial crisis (GFC), was a major worldwide financial crisis centered in the United States. The causes of the 2008 crisis included excessive speculation on housing values by both homeowners ...
, financial economics (and
mathematical finance
Mathematical finance, also known as quantitative finance and financial mathematics, is a field of applied mathematics, concerned with mathematical modeling in the financial field.
In general, there exist two separate branches of finance that req ...
) has been subjected to deeper criticism.
Notable here is
Nassim Taleb, whose critique overlaps the above, but extends
also to the institutional
[Nassim N. Taleb, Daniel G. Goldstein, and Mark W. Spitznagel (2009)]
"The Six Mistakes Executives Make in Risk Management"
'' Harvard Business Review''
aspects of finance - including
academic
An academy (Attic Greek: Ἀκαδήμεια; Koine Greek Ἀκαδημία) is an institution of tertiary education. The name traces back to Plato's school of philosophy, founded approximately 386 BC at Akademia, a sanctuary of Athena, the go ...
.
His
Black swan theory posits that although events of large magnitude and consequence play a major role in finance, since these are (statistically) unexpected,
they are "ignored" by economists and traders.
Thus, although a "
Taleb distribution" - which normally provides a payoff of small positive returns, while carrying a small but significant risk of catastrophic losses - more realistically describes markets than current models, the latter continue to be preferred (even with
professionals here acknowledging that it only "generally works" or only "works on average").
Here,
[Nassim Taleb (2011)]
“Why Did the Crisis of 2008 Happen?”
/ref> financial crises have been a topic of interest
and, in particular, the failure of (financial) economists - as well as bankers
A bank is a financial institution that accepts Deposit account, deposits from the public and creates a demand deposit while simultaneously making loans. Lending activities can be directly performed by the bank or indirectly through capital m ...
and regulators - to model and predict these.
See .
The related problem of systemic risk
In finance, systemic risk is the risk of collapse of an entire financial system or entire market, as opposed to the risk associated with any one individual entity, group or component of a system, that can be contained therein without harming the ...
, has also received attention. Where companies hold securities in each other, then this interconnectedness may entail a "valuation chain" – and the performance of one company, or security, here will impact all, a phenomenon not easily modeled, regardless of whether the individual models are correct. See: Systemic risk § Inadequacy of classic valuation models; Cascades in financial networks; Flight-to-quality
A flight-to-quality, or flight-to-safety, is a financial market phenomenon occurring when investors sell what they perceive to be higher-risk investments and purchase safer investments, such as Gold as an investment, gold and Government bond, gover ...
.
Areas of research attempting to explain (or at least model) these phenomena, and crises, include market microstructure and Heterogeneous agent models, as above. The latter is extended to agent-based computational models; here,[For a survey see: LeBaron, Blake (2006)]
"Agent-based Computational Finance"
''Handbook of Computational Economics''
Elsevier as mentioned, price is treated as an emergent phenomenon, resulting from the interaction of the various market participants (agents). The noisy market hypothesis argues that prices can be influenced by speculators and momentum traders, as well as by insiders and institutions that often buy and sell stocks for reasons unrelated to fundamental value; see Noise (economic) and Noise trader. The adaptive market hypothesis is an attempt to reconcile the efficient market hypothesis with behavioral economics, by applying the principles of evolution
Evolution is the change in the heritable Phenotypic trait, characteristics of biological populations over successive generations. It occurs when evolutionary processes such as natural selection and genetic drift act on genetic variation, re ...
to financial interactions. An information cascade, alternatively, shows market participants engaging in the same acts as others (" herd behavior"), despite contradictions with their private information. Copula-based modelling has similarly been applied. See also Hyman Minsky's "financial instability hypothesis", as well as George Soros' application of "reflexivity".
In the alternative, institutionally inherent limits to arbitrage - i.e. as opposed to factors directly contradictory to the theory - are sometimes referenced.
Note however, that despite the above inefficiencies, asset prices do ''effectively'' follow a random walk - i.e. (at least) in the sense that "changes in the stock market are unpredictable, lacking any pattern that can be used by an investor to beat the overall market".
Thus after fund costs - and given other considerations - it is difficult to consistently outperform market averages
and achieve "alpha".
The practical implication [ William F. Sharpe (2002)]
''Indexed Investing: A Prosaic Way to Beat the Average Investor''
.
Presentation: Monterey Institute of International Studies. Retrieved May 20, 2010. is that passive investing, i.e. via low-cost index fund
An index fund (also index tracker) is a mutual fund or exchange-traded fund (ETF) designed to follow certain preset rules so that it can replicate the performance of a specified basket of underlying investments.
The main advantage of index fun ...
s, should, on average, serve better than any other active strategy -
and, in fact, this practice is now widely adopted.
Here, however, the following concern is posited:
although in concept, it is "the research undertaken by active managers hat
A hat is a Headgear, head covering which is worn for various reasons, including protection against weather conditions, ceremonial reasons such as university graduation, religious reasons, safety, or as a fashion accessory. Hats which incorpor ...
keeps prices closer to value... ndthus there is a fragile equilibrium in which some investors choose to index while the rest continue to search for mispriced securities";
in practice, as more investors "pour money into index funds tracking the same stocks, valuations for those companies become inflated",[James Faris (2025)]
A troubling 'self-fulfilling prophecy' may be forming a market bubble
Business Insider potentially leading to asset bubbles.
See also
* :Finance theories
* :Financial models
*
*
*
* List of financial economics articles
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
Historical notes
References
Bibliography
Financial economics
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
* Volume I ; Volume II .
*
Asset pricing
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
Corporate finance
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
External links
{{Financial risk
Actuarial science