HOME

TheInfoList



OR:

In mathematics, a submodular set function (also known as a submodular function) is a set function whose value, informally, has the property that the difference in the incremental value of the function that a single element makes when added to an input set decreases as the size of the input set increases. Submodular functions have a natural diminishing returns property which makes them suitable for many applications, including approximation algorithms, game theory (as functions modeling user preferences) and
electrical network An electrical network is an interconnection of electrical components (e.g., batteries, resistors, inductors, capacitors, switches, transistors) or a model of such an interconnection, consisting of electrical elements (e.g., voltage sour ...
s. Recently, submodular functions have also found immense utility in several real world problems in
machine learning Machine learning (ML) is a field of inquiry devoted to understanding and building methods that 'learn', that is, methods that leverage data to improve performance on some set of tasks. It is seen as a part of artificial intelligence. Machine ...
and
artificial intelligence Artificial intelligence (AI) is intelligence—perceiving, synthesizing, and inferring information—demonstrated by machine A machine is a physical system using Power (physics), power to apply Force, forces and control Motion, moveme ...
, including automatic summarization, multi-document summarization,
feature selection In machine learning and statistics, feature selection, also known as variable selection, attribute selection or variable subset selection, is the process of selecting a subset of relevant features (variables, predictors) for use in model construc ...
, active learning, sensor placement, image collection summarization and many other domains.


Definition

If \Omega is a finite set, a submodular function is a set function f:2^\rightarrow \mathbb, where 2^\Omega denotes the
power set In mathematics, the power set (or powerset) of a set is the set of all subsets of , including the empty set and itself. In axiomatic set theory (as developed, for example, in the ZFC axioms), the existence of the power set of any set is ...
of \Omega, which satisfies one of the following equivalent conditions. # For every X, Y \subseteq \Omega with X \subseteq Y and every x \in \Omega \setminus Y we have that f(X\cup \)-f(X)\geq f(Y\cup \)-f(Y). # For every S, T \subseteq \Omega we have that f(S)+f(T)\geq f(S\cup T)+f(S\cap T). # For every X\subseteq \Omega and x_1,x_2\in \Omega\backslash X such that x_1\neq x_2 we have that f(X\cup \)+f(X\cup \)\geq f(X\cup \)+f(X). A nonnegative submodular function is also a subadditive function, but a subadditive function need not be submodular. If \Omega is not assumed finite, then the above conditions are not equivalent. In particular a function f defined by f(S) = 1 if S is finite and f(S) = 0 if S is infinite satisfies the first condition above, but the second condition fails when S and T are infinite sets with finite intersection.


Types and examples of submodular functions


Monotone

A submodular function f is ''monotone'' if for every T\subseteq S we have that f(T)\leq f(S). Examples of monotone submodular functions include: ; Linear (Modular) functions : Any function of the form f(S)=\sum_w_i is called a linear function. Additionally if \forall i,w_i\geq 0 then f is monotone. ; Budget-additive functions : Any function of the form f(S)=\min\left\ for each w_i\geq 0 and B\geq 0 is called budget additive. ; Coverage functions : Let \Omega=\ be a collection of subsets of some ground set \Omega'. The function f(S)=\left, \bigcup_E_i\ for S\subseteq \Omega is called a coverage function. This can be generalized by adding non-negative weights to the elements. ;
Entropy Entropy is a scientific concept, as well as a measurable physical property, that is most commonly associated with a state of disorder, randomness, or uncertainty. The term and the concept are used in diverse fields, from classical thermodyna ...
: Let \Omega=\ be a set of random variables. Then for any S\subseteq \Omega we have that H(S) is a submodular function, where H(S) is the entropy of the set of random variables S, a fact known as Shannon's inequality. Further inequalities for the entropy function are known to hold, see entropic vector. ;
Matroid In combinatorics, a branch of mathematics, a matroid is a structure that abstracts and generalizes the notion of linear independence in vector spaces. There are many equivalent ways to define a matroid axiomatically, the most significant being ...
rank functions : Let \Omega=\ be the ground set on which a matroid is defined. Then the rank function of the matroid is a submodular function.Fujishige (2005) p.22


Non-monotone

A submodular function that is not monotone is called ''non-monotone''.


Symmetric

A non-monotone submodular function f is called ''symmetric'' if for every S\subseteq \Omega we have that f(S)=f(\Omega-S). Examples of symmetric non-monotone submodular functions include: ; Graph cuts : Let \Omega=\ be the vertices of a
graph Graph may refer to: Mathematics *Graph (discrete mathematics), a structure made of vertices and edges **Graph theory, the study of such graphs and their properties *Graph (topology), a topological space resembling a graph in the sense of discre ...
. For any set of vertices S\subseteq \Omega let f(S) denote the number of edges e=(u,v) such that u\in S and v\in \Omega-S. This can be generalized by adding non-negative weights to the edges. ;
Mutual information In probability theory and information theory, the mutual information (MI) of two random variables is a measure of the mutual dependence between the two variables. More specifically, it quantifies the " amount of information" (in units such as ...
: Let \Omega=\ be a set of
random variable A random variable (also called random quantity, aleatory variable, or stochastic variable) is a mathematical formalization of a quantity or object which depends on random events. It is a mapping or a function from possible outcomes (e.g., the p ...
s. Then for any S\subseteq \Omega we have that f(S)=I(S;\Omega-S) is a submodular function, where I(S;\Omega-S) is the mutual information.


Asymmetric

A non-monotone submodular function which is not symmetric is called asymmetric. ; Directed cuts : Let \Omega=\ be the vertices of a directed graph. For any set of vertices S\subseteq \Omega let f(S) denote the number of edges e=(u,v) such that u\in S and v\in \Omega-S. This can be generalized by adding non-negative weights to the directed edges.


Continuous extensions


Definition

A set-valued function f:2^\rightarrow \mathbb with , \Omega, =n can also be represented as a function on \^, by associating each S\subseteq \Omega with a binary vector x^\in \^ such that x_^=1 when i\in S, and x_^=0 otherwise. The ''continuous extension'' of f is defined to be any continuous function F: , 1\rightarrow \mathbb such that it matches the value of f on x\in \^, i.e. F(x^)=f(S). In the context of submodular functions, there are a few examples of continuous extensions that are commonly used, which are described as follows.


Examples


Lovász extension

This extension is named after mathematician László Lovász. Consider any vector \mathbf=\ such that each 0\leq x_i\leq 1. Then the Lovász extension is defined as f^L(\mathbf)=\mathbb(f(\)) where the expectation is over \lambda chosen from the
uniform distribution Uniform distribution may refer to: * Continuous uniform distribution * Discrete uniform distribution * Uniform distribution (ecology) * Equidistributed sequence In mathematics, a sequence (''s''1, ''s''2, ''s''3, ...) of real numbers is said to be ...
on the interval ,1/math>. The Lovász extension is a convex function if and only if f is a submodular function.


Multilinear extension

Consider any vector \mathbf=\ such that each 0\leq x_i\leq 1. Then the multilinear extension is defined as F(\mathbf)=\sum_ f(S) \prod_ x_i \prod_ (1-x_i).


Convex closure

Consider any vector \mathbf=\ such that each 0\leq x_i\leq 1. Then the convex closure is defined as f^-(\mathbf)=\min\left(\sum_S \alpha_S f(S):\sum_S \alpha_S 1_S=\mathbf,\sum_S \alpha_S=1,\alpha_S\geq 0\right). The convex closure of any set function is convex over ,1n.


Concave closure

Consider any vector \mathbf=\ such that each 0\leq x_i\leq 1. Then the concave closure is defined as f^+(\mathbf)=\max\left(\sum_S \alpha_S f(S):\sum_S \alpha_S 1_S=\mathbf,\sum_S \alpha_S=1,\alpha_S\geq 0\right).


Connections between extensions

For the extensions discussed above, it can be shown that f^(\mathbf) \geq F(\mathbf) \geq f^(\mathbf)=f^L(\mathbf) when f is submodular.


Properties

# The class of submodular functions is closed under non-negative linear combinations. Consider any submodular function f_1,f_2,\ldots,f_k and non-negative numbers \alpha_1,\alpha_2,\ldots,\alpha_k. Then the function g defined by g(S)=\sum_^k \alpha_i f_i(S) is submodular. #For any submodular function f, the function defined by g(S)=f(\Omega \setminus S) is submodular. #The function g(S)=\min(f(S),c), where c is a real number, is submodular whenever f is monotone submodular. More generally, g(S)=h(f(S)) is submodular, for any non decreasing concave function h. # Consider a random process where a set T is chosen with each element in \Omega being included in T independently with probability p. Then the following inequality is true \mathbb (T)geq p f(\Omega)+(1-p) f(\varnothing) where \varnothing is the empty set. More generally consider the following random process where a set S is constructed as follows. For each of 1\leq i\leq l, A_i\subseteq \Omega construct S_i by including each element in A_i independently into S_i with probability p_i. Furthermore let S=\cup_^l S_i. Then the following inequality is true \mathbb (S)geq \sum_ \Pi_p_i \Pi_(1-p_i)f(\cup_A_i).


Optimization problems

Submodular functions have properties which are very similar to
convex Convex or convexity may refer to: Science and technology * Convex lens, in optics Mathematics * Convex set, containing the whole line segment that joins points ** Convex polygon, a polygon which encloses a convex set of points ** Convex polytop ...
and concave functions. For this reason, an
optimization problem In mathematics, computer science and economics, an optimization problem is the problem of finding the ''best'' solution from all feasible solutions. Optimization problems can be divided into two categories, depending on whether the variables ...
which concerns optimizing a convex or concave function can also be described as the problem of maximizing or minimizing a submodular function subject to some constraints.


Submodular set function minimization

The hardness of minimizing a submodular set function depends on constraints imposed on the problem. # The unconstrained problem of minimizing a submodular function is computable in (strongly)
polynomial time In computer science, the time complexity is the computational complexity that describes the amount of computer time it takes to run an algorithm. Time complexity is commonly estimated by counting the number of elementary operations performed by ...
. Computing the minimum cut in a graph is a special case of this minimization problem. # The problem of minimizing a submodular function with a cardinality lower bound is
NP-hard In computational complexity theory, NP-hardness ( non-deterministic polynomial-time hardness) is the defining property of a class of problems that are informally "at least as hard as the hardest problems in NP". A simple example of an NP-hard pr ...
, with polynomial factor lower bounds on the approximation factor.


Submodular set function maximization

Unlike the case of minimization, maximizing a generic submodular function is
NP-hard In computational complexity theory, NP-hardness ( non-deterministic polynomial-time hardness) is the defining property of a class of problems that are informally "at least as hard as the hardest problems in NP". A simple example of an NP-hard pr ...
even in the unconstrained setting. Thus, most of the works in this field are concerned with polynomial-time approximation algorithms, including
greedy algorithm A greedy algorithm is any algorithm that follows the problem-solving heuristic of making the locally optimal choice at each stage. In many problems, a greedy strategy does not produce an optimal solution, but a greedy heuristic can yield locall ...
s or local search algorithms. # The problem of maximizing a non-negative submodular function admits a 1/2 approximation algorithm. Computing the maximum cut of a graph is a special case of this problem. # The problem of maximizing a monotone submodular function subject to a cardinality constraint admits a 1 - 1/e approximation algorithm. The maximum coverage problem is a special case of this problem. # The problem of maximizing a monotone submodular function subject to a
matroid In combinatorics, a branch of mathematics, a matroid is a structure that abstracts and generalizes the notion of linear independence in vector spaces. There are many equivalent ways to define a matroid axiomatically, the most significant being ...
constraint (which subsumes the case above) also admits a 1 - 1/e approximation algorithm. Many of these algorithms can be unified within a semi-differential based framework of algorithms.


Related optimization problems

Apart from submodular minimization and maximization, there are several other natural optimization problems related to submodular functions. # The difference of submodular optimization problem is not only NP hard, but also inapproximable. # Minimization/maximization of a submodular function subject to a submodular level set constraint (also known as submodular optimization subject to submodular cover or submodular knapsack constraint) admits bounded approximation guarantees. # Partitioning data based on a submodular function to maximize the average welfare is known as the submodular welfare problem, which also admits bounded approximation guarantees.


Applications

Submodular functions naturally occur in several real world applications, in
economics Economics () is the social science that studies the production, distribution, and consumption of goods and services. Economics focuses on the behaviour and interactions of economic agents and how economies work. Microeconomics analy ...
, game theory,
machine learning Machine learning (ML) is a field of inquiry devoted to understanding and building methods that 'learn', that is, methods that leverage data to improve performance on some set of tasks. It is seen as a part of artificial intelligence. Machine ...
and
computer vision Computer vision is an Interdisciplinarity, interdisciplinary scientific field that deals with how computers can gain high-level understanding from digital images or videos. From the perspective of engineering, it seeks to understand and automate t ...
. Owing to the diminishing returns property, submodular functions naturally model costs of items, since there is often a larger discount, with an increase in the items one buys. Submodular functions model notions of complexity, similarity and cooperation when they appear in minimization problems. In maximization problems, on the other hand, they model notions of diversity, information and coverage.


See also

*
Supermodular function In mathematics, a function :f\colon \mathbb^k \to \mathbb is supermodular if : f(x \uparrow y) + f(x \downarrow y) \geq f(x) + f(y) for all x, y \isin \mathbb^, where x \uparrow y denotes the componentwise maximum and x \downarrow y the componentw ...
*
Matroid In combinatorics, a branch of mathematics, a matroid is a structure that abstracts and generalizes the notion of linear independence in vector spaces. There are many equivalent ways to define a matroid axiomatically, the most significant being ...
, Polymatroid * Utility functions on indivisible goods


Citations


References

* * * * *{{citation , last=Oxley , first=James G. , title=Matroid theory , series=Oxford Science Publications , location=Oxford , publisher=
Oxford University Press Oxford University Press (OUP) is the university press of the University of Oxford. It is the largest university press in the world, and its printing history dates back to the 1480s. Having been officially granted the legal right to print book ...
, year=1992 , isbn=0-19-853563-5 , zbl=0784.05002


External links

* http://www.cs.berkeley.edu/~stefje/references.html has a longer bibliography * http://submodularity.org/ includes further material on the subject Matroid theory