Simple commodity production (, also translated as petty commodity production), is a term coined by
Friedrich Engels
Friedrich Engels ( ;"Engels" ''Random House Webster's Unabridged Dictionary''.Karl Marx
Karl Marx (; 5 May 1818 – 14 March 1883) was a German philosopher, political theorist, economist, journalist, and revolutionary socialist. He is best-known for the 1848 pamphlet '' The Communist Manifesto'' (written with Friedrich Engels) ...
had called the "simple exchange" or "simple circulation" of
commodities
In economics, a commodity is an economic good, usually a resource, that specifically has full or substantial fungibility: that is, the market treats instances of the good as equivalent or nearly so with no regard to who produced them.
Th ...
, where independent producers trade their own products to obtain other products of equivalent value. The use of the adjective ''simple'' is not intended to refer to the nature of the producers or of their production, but rather to the relatively simple and straightforward exchange processes involved, from an economic perspective.
As discussed below, both
Karl Marx
Karl Marx (; 5 May 1818 – 14 March 1883) was a German philosopher, political theorist, economist, journalist, and revolutionary socialist. He is best-known for the 1848 pamphlet '' The Communist Manifesto'' (written with Friedrich Engels) ...
law of value
The law of the value of commodities (German: ''Wertgesetz der Waren''), known simply as the law of value, is a central concept in Karl Marx's critique of political economy first expounded in his polemic ''The Poverty of Philosophy'' (1847) agains ...
applied also to simple exchange, and that the operation of this law is modified (or, as Marx sometimes says, "inverted") by the capitalist mode of production when all the inputs and outputs of production (including
means of production
In political philosophy, the means of production refers to the generally necessary assets and resources that enable a society to engage in production. While the exact resources encompassed in the term may vary, it is widely agreed to include the ...
and
labour power
Labour power (; ) is the capacity to work, a key concept used by Karl Marx in his critique of capitalist political economy. Marx distinguished between the capacity to do the work, i.e. labour power, and the physical act of working, i.e. labour. ...
) become tradeable commodities. Many classical economists were aware of differences between simple commodity exchange and capitalist exchange, but they could not adequately explain the historical transformation of the one into the other. Sometimes their theories confused simple commodity trade with capitalist commodity trade.
According to Marx and Engels, simple commodity production and trade existed for millennia before the advent of industrial capitalism. From the beginnings of the bourgeois epoch in 15th century Europe, the reach and scope of commodity production began to grow incrementally, although sometimes this process was interrupted by wars, epidemic diseases, power relations and natural disasters. Only with the growth of free
wage labour
Wage labour (also wage labor in American English), usually referred to as paid work, paid employment, or paid labour, refers to the socioeconomic relationship between a worker and an employer in which the worker sells their labour power under ...
is commodity production generalized (''verallgemeinert'') to most of the economy, and fully integrated into national and international markets. Obviously, this market growth ''also'' required institutions, conventions and rules, so that the competing burghers could resolve their trade disputes fairly and efficiently, without destroying the markets and destroying people's livelihoods; through learning from experience as well as from the invention and widespread adoption of new ideas, a "market culture" gradually evolved to make that possible.
Civil society
Civil society can be understood as the "third sector" of society, distinct from government and business, and including the family and the private sphere.subsistence
A subsistence economy is an economy directed to basic subsistence (the provision of food, clothing and shelter) rather than to the market.
Definition
"Subsistence" is understood as supporting oneself and family at a minimum level. Basic subsiste ...
production (see also natural economy). That continued for millennia until
urbanization
Urbanization (or urbanisation in British English) is the population shift from Rural area, rural to urban areas, the corresponding decrease in the proportion of people living in rural areas, and the ways in which societies adapt to this change. ...
industrialization
Industrialisation (British English, UK) American and British English spelling differences, or industrialization (American English, US) is the period of social and economic change that transforms a human group from an agrarian society into an i ...
began to take off. Through the last six centuries, the share of commodity production in total output grew more and more, together with productivity growth and population growth. It grew steeply in the 19th and 20th centuries, until production for the market represented the largest part of total output value in the majority of countries.
To explain this lengthy historical process, Marx and Engels took a nuanced approach. They did not argue crudely that economic categories can only be ''either'' "transhistorical categories" ''or'' "categories specific to one historical period". Instead, they argued that economic categories can and do ''evolve'' from one historical epoch to the next, along with the evolution of the social relations which they express. Transitional phases and forms occurred, and continuities co-existed with discontinuities. Marx and Engels were both very aware that historically there existed ''gradations'' of market integration, and that the achievement of full market integration was a very lengthy and complex historical process. The challenge was to understand dialectically, how the new economic relations could evolve out of the old ones - by retaining some of their content, losing some content, and also gaining some completely new content. Historically, the simple production and exchange of commodities ''evolved'', it took different forms, and showed varying degrees of sophistication.
Different interpretations
This historical, evolutionary viewpoint is however not accepted by all Marxists. The historical role of simple exchange based on simple commodity production has been the subject of considerable controversy among Marxist scholars. It has been claimed by academics that Marx never had a concept of "simple commodity production" because he did not use those words. If that is true, then it seems that Engels's concept is really alien to Marx's thought. For example, the Italian Marx-scholar Roberto Fineschi alleges that
Friedrich Engels
Friedrich Engels ( ;"Engels" ''Random House Webster's Unabridged Dictionary''.David Harvey, "Value... becomes an embedded regulatory norm in the sphere of exchange only under conditions of capital accumulation". Christopher J. Arthur claims that an economy or society fully based on simple commodity production has never existed in history, contrary to what Engels (allegedly) suggested.
Some Marxists believe that capitalist markets function in a "totally different way" from pre-capitalist markets, or they believe that the
law of value
The law of the value of commodities (German: ''Wertgesetz der Waren''), known simply as the law of value, is a central concept in Karl Marx's critique of political economy first expounded in his polemic ''The Poverty of Philosophy'' (1847) agains ...
applies only to industrial capitalism, and not to market systems which preceded industrial capitalism. According to Helmut Reichelt, for example, the law of value only applies when the whole of society is subsumed under the bourgeois form of the division of labour. Alex Callinicos argues that "the so-called historical interpretation of the labour theory of value" which claims that "it holds true in conditions of simple commodity production, prior to the development of capitalism", involves "a complete misunderstanding of Marx’s value theory". Following John Weeks and Robert Brenner, Callinicos claims that if an independent producer produces his own outputs with his own means of production, and sells some of them in the village market, then no “commodity production” occurs at all, because his inputs for production are not commodities, and the production process is not subject to the laws of competition. Therefore, to call such production “simple commodity production” is simply wrong. Engels aimed to give a consistent explanation of the evolution and development of the market economy, from simple beginnings to the complexities of modern capitalist markets, but his critics argue he disregards the qualitative transformation of the
relations of production
Relations of production () is a concept frequently used by Karl Marx and Friedrich Engels in their theory of historical materialism and in ''Das Kapital''. It is first explicitly used in Marx's published book '' The Poverty of Philosophy'', al ...
involved.
The new anti-Engels interpretation is contrary to the traditional Marxist view, the latter which defines a commodity as a ''product of labour'' and not (as academic
value-form
The value-form or form of value (''"Wertform"'' in German) is an important concept in Karl Marx's critique of political economy, discussed in the first chapter of ''Capital, Volume 1''. It refers to the ''social form'' of tradeable things as un ...
theorists do) as a ''product of exchange''. According to the traditional Marxist view, the simple exchange of commodities ''presupposes'' at least that the commodities are ''produced''. Otherwise there ''would not exist'' any commodities that could be exchanged. Historically speaking, the development of the simple exchange of reproducible commodities could never occur without simple commodity production. Engels does not argue that the law of value ''disappears'' when commodity trade is regulated by production prices, but rather that the law of value is ''transformed'' and ''modified''. It is transformed, because:
*Originally (as already recognized by
Adam Smith
Adam Smith (baptised 1723 – 17 July 1790) was a Scottish economist and philosopher who was a pioneer in the field of political economy and key figure during the Scottish Enlightenment. Seen by some as the "father of economics"——— or ...
) the exchange-value of what a producer creates is regulated by his own necessary labour-time (with upper and lower limits). But, in the end, what regulates the exchange-value of his production is ''a socially average labour-cost'', i.e. a value expressed as the normal price-level which is imposed on him as an objective external force (like "a law of nature") - regardless of whether his own labour-time is more or less than the normal social average. Paradoxically, as Marx says, the more that the producers become dependent on exchange, the more exchange appears to become independent of them.
*The simple exchange of labour-equivalents as the basis for balanced trade is gradually replaced by the more complex exchange of unequal labour-values, where fluctuating market-prices for products systematically diverge from average product-values, and their supply-cost contains a
surplus value
In Marxian economics, surplus value is the difference between the amount raised through a sale of a product and the amount it cost to manufacture it: i.e. the amount raised through sale of the product minus the cost of the materials, plant and ...
formed in production. The exchange-values of products are no longer directly regulated by labour-values, but by prices of production (although the
law of value
The law of the value of commodities (German: ''Wertgesetz der Waren''), known simply as the law of value, is a central concept in Karl Marx's critique of political economy first expounded in his polemic ''The Poverty of Philosophy'' (1847) agains ...
ultimately still sets limits on price fluctuations). What therefore determines commodity prices at this stage are the average cost-prices and the average profit yields from their production and sale (the rates and volumes of profit).
*While originally the commodities sold were a surplus to the requirements of the seller, alongside subsistence production, eventually the market sale of the commodities produced is the precondition and the only practical purpose of producing them. In contrast to ''partial'' commodity production, ''generalized'' (universalized) commodity production means that all the inputs of production are supplied as commodities, and all the outputs are sold as commodities - with the consequence, that the whole production process is reorganized to conform to commercial criteria. This is the economic background for the transition from the ''formal'' subsumption of labour and production under capital (extraction of absolute surplus value from wage-labour, by increasing hours worked up to the absolute upper limit) to its ''real'' subsumption (extraction of relative surplus value, by increasing the productivity of wage-labour with better means of production, tools and techniques).
Instead of postulating a "society of simple commodity producers", Engels was referring to the history of the gradual expansion of commodity-trade alongside subsistence production across thousands of years, to more and more sectors of economic life - until commodity production is generalized and the majority of commodities are produced "by means of commodities" in capitalist enterprises employing
wage labour
Wage labour (also wage labor in American English), usually referred to as paid work, paid employment, or paid labour, refers to the socioeconomic relationship between a worker and an employer in which the worker sells their labour power under ...
. Marx had briefly indicated this historical process himself in his 1864 manuscript ''Results of the immediate process of production''.
In the anti-Engels explanation, it is unclear what regulates commodity-trade in the pre-capitalist economy, if not the
law of value
The law of the value of commodities (German: ''Wertgesetz der Waren''), known simply as the law of value, is a central concept in Karl Marx's critique of political economy first expounded in his polemic ''The Poverty of Philosophy'' (1847) agains ...
. It is unclear how the law of value can "suddenly" appear out of nowhere, once most of production becomes commodity production through the growth of markets. Apparently, capital began to exist ''when wage-labour exists'', i.e. when peasants and serfs were thrown off the land and were forced to work for a wage from an employer, to make a living. Somehow, a mass of employers "suddenly" appears out of nowhere to employ a mass of unemployed workers in mechanized factories, in exchange for wages. But how this could have resulted from the situation that preceded it, remains a puzzle.
This mystery is solved only when labour history is studied. Long before the industrial capitalist appeared on the stage of history, wage-labourers were already being hired - when officials of the early state paid soldiers for their services, temple officials employed contract labourers, and landowners hired farm workers. The first known workers' strike recorded in written history, on a
papyrus
Papyrus ( ) is a material similar to thick paper that was used in ancient times as a writing surface. It was made from the pith of the papyrus plant, ''Cyperus papyrus'', a wetland sedge. ''Papyrus'' (plural: ''papyri'' or ''papyruses'') can a ...
, was staged more than three thousand years ago by building workers at the royal
necropolis
A necropolis (: necropolises, necropoles, necropoleis, necropoli) is a large, designed cemetery with elaborate tomb monuments. The name stems from the Ancient Greek ''nekropolis'' ().
The term usually implies a separate burial site at a distan ...
at
Deir el-Medina
Deir el-Medina (), or Dayr al-Madīnah, is an ancient Egyptian workmen's village which was home to the artisans who worked on the tombs in the Valley of the Kings during the 18th to 20th Dynasties of the New Kingdom of Egypt (ca. 1550–1080 BC). ...
in
Egypt
Egypt ( , ), officially the Arab Republic of Egypt, is a country spanning the Northeast Africa, northeast corner of Africa and Western Asia, southwest corner of Asia via the Sinai Peninsula. It is bordered by the Mediterranean Sea to northe ...
Simple exchange of reproducible and portable commodities (such as foodstuffs, ornaments, beads, pottery, pelts, fabrics, clothing, tools, utensils, and weapons) is as old as the history of
trade
Trade involves the transfer of goods and services from one person or entity to another, often in exchange for money. Economists refer to a system or network that allows trade as a market.
Traders generally negotiate through a medium of cr ...
, insofar as it progressed from incidental
barter
In trade, barter (derived from ''bareter'') is a system of exchange (economics), exchange in which participants in a financial transaction, transaction directly exchange good (economics), goods or service (economics), services for other goods ...
of
use-value
Use value () or value in use is a concept in classical political economy and Marxist economics. It refers to the tangible features of a Commodity (Marxism), commodity (a tradeable object) which can satisfy some human requirement, want or need, o ...
s according to cultural custom, to regular exchange using a standard of value. Simple exchange occurred for thousands of years before most production became organized in the
capitalist
Capitalism is an economic system based on the private ownership of the means of production and their use for the purpose of obtaining profit. This socioeconomic system has developed historically through several stages and is defined by ...
way. It begins when producers in a simple
division of labour
The division of labour is the separation of the tasks in any economic system or organisation so that participants may specialise ( specialisation). Individuals, organisations, and nations are endowed with or acquire specialised capabilities, a ...
(e.g. farmers, hunters/gatherers and artisans) trade surpluses to their own requirements, with the aim of obtaining other products with an equivalent value, for their own use. In Marx's own words,
Through the experience of regular trade and competition, normal
exchange value
In political economy and especially Marxian economics, exchange value () refers to one of the four major attributes of a commodity, i.e., an item or service produced for, and sold on the market, the other three attributes being use value, econo ...
s become established for products, which reflect an economy of labour-time and a cost-structure of production. The simple commodity producers could aim just to trade their products or services to obtain other products with an equivalent value, or they could, in favourable circumstances, aim to realise a profit. They could sell their products or services to the final consumer, or to an intermediary such as a merchant. Simple commodity production and simple exchange are compatible with many different relations of production and exchange, ranging from
self-employment
Self-employment is the state of working for oneself rather than an employer. Tax authorities will generally view a person as self-employed if the person chooses to be recognised as such or if the person is generating income for which a tax return ...
in which the producer owns his own means of production and family (household) labour, to forms of
slavery
Slavery is the ownership of a person as property, especially in regards to their labour. Slavery typically involves compulsory work, with the slave's location of work and residence dictated by the party that holds them in bondage. Enslavemen ...
,
peonage
Peon ( English , from the Spanish '' peón'' ) usually refers to a person subject to peonage: any form of wage labor, financial exploitation, coercive economic practice, or policy in which the victim or a laborer (peon) has little control ove ...
serfdom
Serfdom was the status of many peasants under feudalism, specifically relating to manorialism and similar systems. It was a condition of debt bondage and indentured servitude with similarities to and differences from slavery. It developed du ...
. In the cooperative farming system of the
Soviet Union
The Union of Soviet Socialist Republics. (USSR), commonly known as the Soviet Union, was a List of former transcontinental countries#Since 1700, transcontinental country that spanned much of Eurasia from 1922 until Dissolution of the Soviet ...
, members of the
kolkhoz
A kolkhoz ( rus, колхо́з, a=ru-kolkhoz.ogg, p=kɐlˈxos) was a form of collective farm in the Soviet Union. Kolkhozes existed along with state farms or sovkhoz. These were the two components of the socialized farm sector that began to eme ...
y were permitted to cultivate small plots of private farmland, to raise some livestock, and to sell their produce themselves.
The technologies used by a simple commodity producer might be characteristic for a specific mode of production, but simple commodity production as such is not specific to any particular
mode of production
In the Marxist theory of historical materialism, a mode of production (German: ''Produktionsweise'', "the way of producing") is a specific combination of the:
* Productive forces: these include human labour power and means of production (tools, ...
, and might be found alongside (or articulated with) many different modes of production, with various degrees of sophistication. It does not necessarily imply that ''all'' the inputs or outputs of productive activity in the local economy are
commodities
In economics, a commodity is an economic good, usually a resource, that specifically has full or substantial fungibility: that is, the market treats instances of the good as equivalent or nearly so with no regard to who produced them.
Th ...
traded in markets. For example, simple commodity producers could produce some products for their own subsistence and for their own use on their own land, while trading another part of their products. They might buy or trade some tools and equipment, but also make some tools and equipment themselves. Simple commodity production continues to occur in capitalist societies, especially in developing countries.
Early settler colonies
A society which literally consisted ''only'' of simple commodity producers has never existed, and
Friedrich Engels
Friedrich Engels ( ;"Engels" ''Random House Webster's Unabridged Dictionary''.North America
North America is a continent in the Northern Hemisphere, Northern and Western Hemisphere, Western hemispheres. North America is bordered to the north by the Arctic Ocean, to the east by the Atlantic Ocean, to the southeast by South Ameri ...
,
Argentina
Argentina, officially the Argentine Republic, is a country in the southern half of South America. It covers an area of , making it the List of South American countries by area, second-largest country in South America after Brazil, the fourt ...
,
South Africa
South Africa, officially the Republic of South Africa (RSA), is the Southern Africa, southernmost country in Africa. Its Provinces of South Africa, nine provinces are bounded to the south by of coastline that stretches along the Atlantic O ...
,
Australia
Australia, officially the Commonwealth of Australia, is a country comprising mainland Australia, the mainland of the Australia (continent), Australian continent, the island of Tasmania and list of islands of Australia, numerous smaller isl ...
and
New Zealand
New Zealand () is an island country in the southwestern Pacific Ocean. It consists of two main landmasses—the North Island () and the South Island ()—and List of islands of New Zealand, over 600 smaller islands. It is the List of isla ...
- this aspect is disregarded totally by Christopher J. Arthur). In these settler colonies, initially there existed no class of landowners who owned most of the land. Marx was well aware of this, and he remarked wrily that in the colonies "the capitalist regime constantly comes up against the obstacle presented by the producer, who, as owner of his own conditions of labour, employs that labour to enrich himself instead of the capitalist".). In his discussion of colonization in ''Capital, Vol. 1'', Marx illustrates the colonial labour problem with an anecdote about an English entrepreneur who decided to emigrate to Australia:
In the colony, there existed no absolute necessity or socio-economic compulsion to work for an employer, and many workers ran off, to go into business for themselves, or to find better jobs and wages in
Perth
Perth () is the list of Australian capital cities, capital city of Western Australia. It is the list of cities in Australia by population, fourth-most-populous city in Australia, with a population of over 2.3 million within Greater Perth . The ...
,
Sydney
Sydney is the capital city of the States and territories of Australia, state of New South Wales and the List of cities in Australia by population, most populous city in Australia. Located on Australia's east coast, the metropolis surrounds Syd ...
and other settlements in Australia.
An American historian comments that:
The proportion of early American colonists who worked as artisans is estimated to have been between 10% and 18%. So the vast majority of the workforce at that time (up to about 93%) consisted not of waged employees, but of independent farmers and artisans engaging in simple commodity production. Imported African slaves "worked mainly on the tobacco, rice and indigo plantations of the southern coast, from the
Chesapeake Bay
The Chesapeake Bay ( ) is the largest estuary in the United States. The bay is located in the Mid-Atlantic (United States), Mid-Atlantic region and is primarily separated from the Atlantic Ocean by the Delmarva Peninsula, including parts of the Ea ...
colonies of
Maryland
Maryland ( ) is a U.S. state, state in the Mid-Atlantic (United States), Mid-Atlantic region of the United States. It borders the states of Virginia to its south, West Virginia to its west, Pennsylvania to its north, and Delaware to its east ...
and
Virginia
Virginia, officially the Commonwealth of Virginia, is a U.S. state, state in the Southeastern United States, Southeastern and Mid-Atlantic (United States), Mid-Atlantic regions of the United States between the East Coast of the United States ...
south to
Georgia
Georgia most commonly refers to:
* Georgia (country), a country in the South Caucasus
* Georgia (U.S. state), a state in the southeastern United States
Georgia may also refer to:
People and fictional characters
* Georgia (name), a list of pe ...
." Before 1660, few Virginia planters owned slaves. By 1675 the use of slaves was common, and by 1700 slaves largely replaced indentured servants. "With plentiful land and slave labor available to grow a lucrative crop, southern planters prospered, and family-based tobacco plantations became the economic and social norm". In hindsight, Marx concluded that:
From the time of the earliest English colonial settlements of the 1600s until America began to issue its own currency in 1783, three different types of money were used in colonial commodity trade: (1) coins (
Spanish dollar
The Spanish dollar, also known as the piece of eight (, , , or ), is a silver coin of approximately diameter worth eight Spanish reales. It was minted in the Spanish Empire following a monetary reform in 1497 with content fine silver. It w ...
s,
shillings
The shilling is a historical coin, and the name of a unit of modern currencies formerly used in the United Kingdom, Australia, New Zealand, other British Commonwealth countries and Ireland, where they were generally equivalent to 12 pence ...
), (2 paper notes (fiat money denominated in British pounds, shillings and pence; land notes; bank notes; tobacco notes) and (3 (portable goods and services offered in exchange, including tobacco, corn,
wampum
Wampum is a traditional shell bead of the Eastern Woodlands tribes of Native Americans. It includes white shell beads hand-fashioned from the North Atlantic channeled whelk shell and white and purple beads made from the quahog or Western ...
, buttons, etc.).
Textual sources of the concept
In ''
The Wealth of Nations
''An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations'', usually referred to by its shortened title ''The Wealth of Nations'', is a book by the Scottish people, Scottish economist and moral philosophy, moral philosopher Adam Smith; ...
'' (1776),
Adam Smith
Adam Smith (baptised 1723 – 17 July 1790) was a Scottish economist and philosopher who was a pioneer in the field of political economy and key figure during the Scottish Enlightenment. Seen by some as the "father of economics"——— or ...
introduces the concept of simple commodity production as follows:
Smith then contrasts simple commodity production with capitalist production involving wage labour:
In a conspectus and critique of
Adam Smith
Adam Smith (baptised 1723 – 17 July 1790) was a Scottish economist and philosopher who was a pioneer in the field of political economy and key figure during the Scottish Enlightenment. Seen by some as the "father of economics"——— or ...
's theory of value, Marx similarly gives a brief description of simple commodity production (although admittedly he did not use that terminology):
In this situation of simple exchange, Marx concludes, a given quantity of living labour would ordinarily always command an equivalent amount of labour objectified in commodities. However, he continues, in all modes of production where one or more social classes own the means of production, while commoners own only their ability to work for a living, this general equivalence does not exist (because commoners perform
surplus labour
Surplus labor () is a concept used by Karl Marx in his critique of political economy. It means labor performed in excess of the labor necessary to produce the means of livelihood of the worker ("necessary labor"). The "surplus" in this context mea ...
). That is why Adam Smith mistakenly draws the conclusion, that when wage-labour coexists with capital and landed property, labour is no longer “the immanent measure which regulates the exchange value of commodities”. Smith should have concluded instead, that the expressions “quantity of labour” and “value of labour” are no longer the same in a class society (which, Marx notes, was later pointed out by
David Ricardo
David Ricardo (18 April 1772 – 11 September 1823) was a British political economist, politician, and member of Parliament. He is recognized as one of the most influential classical economists, alongside figures such as Thomas Malthus, Ada ...
).
In his 1894 preface to ''Capital, Volume 3'', Friedrich Engels argued that:
This interpretation by Engels closely followed what Marx himself stated in his 1864 manuscript titled ''Results of the immediate process of production'':
However, the interpretation by Engels arguably did not completely match what Marx said about his own approach. In his critical notes on Adolph Wagner's ''Textbook on political economy'' (1879), Marx said about his analysis of the commodity form in ''Capital, Volume 1'' that:
Here Marx states clearly, that in the first chapter of ''Capital Vol. 1'' he was talking about the commodity as the simplest traded object "in ''contemporary society''", and ''not'' about a simple commodity in ''pre-capitalist'' society. Point is, when Marx first analyzes a commodity as such (as a very simple category of trade), he disregards how exactly the commodity is produced and how specifically it is traded. He just examines the commodity (in his own words) "as an autonomous article", as a separate thing just as it observably appears in an everyday trading relation - without introducing all sorts of assumptions about how and where it originated, or what it will be used for. Put another way, Marx is talking about simple commodity ''circulation'', not simple commodity ''production'', although the former could assume the latter (the simple exchange of a commodity could be preceded by different forms of producing it).
In his 1895 afterword ''Supplement and addendum to Volume 3 of Capital'', Friedrich Engels elaborates the concept of simple commodity production as follows:
Again, Engels based himself on (and references) what Marx himself had said – in chapter 10 of ''Capital, Volume 3'' (on the equalization of rates of profit by competition):
From simple commodity production to capitalist production
The large-scale global transformation of simple commodity production into capitalist production based on the
wage labour
Wage labour (also wage labor in American English), usually referred to as paid work, paid employment, or paid labour, refers to the socioeconomic relationship between a worker and an employer in which the worker sells their labour power under ...
of employees occurred only in the last two centuries of human history. It is preceded by the strong growth of
merchant
A merchant is a person who trades in goods produced by other people, especially one who trades with foreign countries. Merchants have been known for as long as humans have engaged in trade and commerce. Merchants and merchant networks operated i ...
trade, supported by credit from financiers who earn rents, profit and interest from the process.The merchants not only act as intermediary between producers and consumers, but also integrate more and more of production into a market economy. That is, more and more is produced for the purpose of market trade, rather than for own use. The initial result is known as " merchant capitalism", which flourished in Western European cities especially in the 17th and 18th centuries but already existed on a smaller scale in the 15th century and even earlier.
However, the transformation of more and more simple commodity production into capitalist production which accompanies
industrialisation
Industrialisation ( UK) or industrialization ( US) is the period of social and economic change that transforms a human group from an agrarian society into an industrial society. This involves an extensive reorganisation of an economy for th ...
requires profound changes in
property
Property is a system of rights that gives people legal control of valuable things, and also refers to the valuable things themselves. Depending on the nature of the property, an owner of property may have the right to consume, alter, share, re ...
relations, because it must be possible to trade freely in
means of production
In political philosophy, the means of production refers to the generally necessary assets and resources that enable a society to engage in production. While the exact resources encompassed in the term may vary, it is widely agreed to include the ...
(materials, equipment, buildings, installations and land) and
labour power
Labour power (; ) is the capacity to work, a key concept used by Karl Marx in his critique of capitalist political economy. Marx distinguished between the capacity to do the work, i.e. labour power, and the physical act of working, i.e. labour. ...
(the
factors of production
In economics, factors of production, resources, or inputs are what is used in the production process to produce output—that is, goods and services. The utilised amounts of the various inputs determine the quantity of output according to the rela ...
). Only when that trade becomes possible, can the whole of production be reorganised to conform to commercial principles.
Marx describes capitalist society as "a society where the commodity-form is the universal form of the product of labour, hence the dominant social relation is the relation between people as possessors of commodities". He argues that "The capitalist epoch is... characterized by the fact that labour-power, in the eyes of the worker himself, takes on the form of a commodity which is his property; his labour consequently takes on the form of wage-labour... it is only from this moment that the commodity-form of the products of labour becomes universal." Thus, "...from the moment there is a free sale, by the worker himself, of labour power as a commodity... from then onwards... commodity production is generalized and becomes the typical form of production."
In an 1864 manuscript, Marx emphasized specifically that:
To reach the stage of a universal market, many legal, political, religious and technical restrictions imposed on commercial trade must be overcome. The unification of a "home market" among people in a country who can speak the same language typically stimulated
nationalist
Nationalism is an idea or movement that holds that the nation should be congruent with the State (polity), state. As a movement, it presupposes the existence and tends to promote the interests of a particular nation,Anthony D. Smith, Smith, A ...
ideologies. But depending on the existing social systems, the transformation might occur in many different ways. Typically, though, it has involved wars, violence and
revolution
In political science, a revolution (, 'a turn around') is a rapid, fundamental transformation of a society's class, state, ethnic or religious structures. According to sociologist Jack Goldstone, all revolutions contain "a common set of elements ...
s, since people were unwilling to just give away assets, rights and income that they previously had. Communally owned property, hereditary land ownership, the property of religious orders and state property all had to be privatised and amalgamated, in order to become tradeable assets in the process of
capital accumulation
Capital accumulation is the dynamic that motivates the pursuit of profit, involving the investment of money or any financial asset with the goal of increasing the initial monetary value of said asset as a financial return whether in the form ...
. The
ideology
An ideology is a set of beliefs or values attributed to a person or group of persons, especially those held for reasons that are not purely about belief in certain knowledge, in which "practical elements are as prominent as theoretical ones". Form ...
of the rising
bourgeoisie
The bourgeoisie ( , ) are a class of business owners, merchants and wealthy people, in general, which emerged in the Late Middle Ages, originally as a "middle class" between the peasantry and aristocracy. They are traditionally contrasted wi ...
typically emphasized the benefits of privately owned property for the purpose of wealth creation and industriousness.
Marx refers to this process as the primitive accumulation of capital, a process which continues particularly in developing countries to this day. Marx shows that primitive accumulation involves to a large extent the expropriation of independent producers, who lose their means of production, and therefore are forced to work for an employer to earn a living. Typically, previously independent producers on the land (but also
serfs
Serfdom was the status of many peasants under feudalism, specifically relating to manorialism and similar systems. It was a condition of debt bondage and indentured servitude with similarities to and differences from slavery. It developed dur ...
and indentured labourers etc.) are proletarianised and migrate to the urban centres, in search of work from an employer.
Simple commodity production nevertheless continues to occur on a large scale in the world economy, particularly in
peasant
A peasant is a pre-industrial agricultural laborer or a farmer with limited land-ownership, especially one living in the Middle Ages under feudalism and paying rent, tax, fees, or services to a landlord. In Europe, three classes of peasan ...
production. It also persists within industrialised capitalist economies in the form of self-employment by free producers. Capitalist firms sometimes contract out specialised services to self-employed producers, who can produce them at a lower cost, or provide a superior product. Many digital products are produced by self-employed specialists who own their own computer (but who also depend on internet providers, and on access to rented software and websites).
Modelling simple commodity production
The historical example of early settler colonies suggests that an "imaginary society" of simple commodity producers temporarily became a reality, as an early phase in the evolution of new social formations. In that sense, a "socety of simple commodity producers" ''did' exist for a while. However, in some schools of
Marxian economics
Marxian economics, or the Marxian school of economics, is a heterodox school of political economic thought. Its foundations can be traced back to Karl Marx's critique of political economy. However, unlike critics of political economy, Marxian ...
, simple commodity production refers only to a model of a ''hypothetical'' economy (or an "imaginary society") used by economists to interpret some of
Karl Marx
Karl Marx (; 5 May 1818 – 14 March 1883) was a German philosopher, political theorist, economist, journalist, and revolutionary socialist. He is best-known for the 1848 pamphlet '' The Communist Manifesto'' (written with Friedrich Engels) ...
's insights about the economic laws governing the development of commodity trade. The model is only a
thought experiment
A thought experiment is an imaginary scenario that is meant to elucidate or test an argument or theory. It is often an experiment that would be hard, impossible, or unethical to actually perform. It can also be an abstract hypothetical that is ...
to identify some quantitative implications of commercial production and trade. In this society, a
market economy
A market economy is an economic system in which the decisions regarding investment, production, and distribution to the consumers are guided by the price signals created by the forces of supply and demand. The major characteristic of a mark ...
is supposed in which all producers are independent individuals who own and operate their own means of production, and who trade their own products. According to Michio Morishima,
Ronald L. Meek explains:
Theoretical discussion
The theoretical debates about simple commodity production have attracted contributions from numerous economists, philosophers and historians across the last century. This seemingly obscure topic has important implications for quite a few different areas of research:
*The interpretation of Marx’s method of analysis and his theory of value;
*The interpretation of the historical transition from pre-capitalist society to capitalism (and more generally, the social history of trade and marketization and the evolution of the forms of economic value);
*The so-called
transformation problem
In 20th-century discussions of Karl Marx's economics, the transformation problem is the problem of finding a general rule by which to transform the "values" of commodities (based on their socially necessary labour content, according to his labo ...
;
*Understanding
settler colonialism
Settler colonialism is a logic and structure of displacement by Settler, settlers, using colonial rule, over an environment for replacing it and its indigenous peoples with settlements and the society of the settlers.
Settler colonialism is ...
development economics
Development economics is a branch of economics that deals with economic aspects of the development process in low- and middle- income countries. Its focus is not only on methods of promoting economic development, economic growth and structural c ...
;
*The economics of the transition from capitalism to socialism and communism (the gradual replacement of market allocation by direct allocation).
Contributors to the theoretical discussion have included Michael von Tugan-Baranowsky,
Nikolai Bukharin
Nikolai Ivanovich Bukharin (; rus, Николай Иванович Бухарин, p=nʲɪkɐˈlaj ɪˈvanəvʲɪdʑ bʊˈxarʲɪn; – 15 March 1938) was a Russian revolutionary, Soviet politician, and Marxist theorist. A prominent Bolshevik ...
,
Karl Kautsky
Karl Johann Kautsky (; ; 16 October 1854 – 17 October 1938) was a Czech-Austrian Marxism, Marxist theorist. A leading theorist of the Social Democratic Party of Germany (SPD) and the Second International, Kautsky advocated orthodox Marxism, a ...
,
Rudolf Hilferding
Rudolf Hilferding (; 10 August 1877 – 11 February 1941) was an Austrian-born Marxist economist, Socialism, socialist theorist,International Institute of Social History, ''Rudolf Hilferding Papers'': http://www.iisg.nl/archives/en/files/h/1075 ...
Paul Sweezy
Paul Marlor Sweezy (April 10, 1910 – February 27, 2004) was a Marxist economist, political activist, publisher, and founding editor of the long-running magazine ''Monthly Review''. He is best remembered for his contributions to economic theory ...
,
Piero Sraffa
Piero Sraffa Fellow of the British Academy, FBA (5 August 1898 – 3 September 1983) was an influential Italian Political economy, political economist who served as lecturer of economics at the University of Cambridge. His book ''Production of Co ...
Joan Robinson
Joan Violet Robinson ( Maurice; 31 October 1903 – 5 August 1983) was a British economist known for her wide-ranging contributions to economic theory. One of the most prominent economists of the century, Robinson incarnated the "Cambridge Sc ...
,
Isaak Illich Rubin
Isaak Illich Rubin (Russian language, Russian: Исаак Ильич Рубин; 12 June 1886 – 27 November 1937) was a Soviet Union, Soviet lawyer, Marxian economics , economist and scholar of Marx's work. His most important published work ...
,
Roman Rosdolsky
Roman Osipovich Rosdolsky (, ''Roman Osypovyč Rozdol's'kyj''; July 19, 1898 – October 20, 1967) was a prominent Ukrainian Marxian scholar, historian and political theorist. Rodolsky's book of 1968 entitled ''Zur Entstehungsgeschichte des Mar ...
Ernest Mandel
Ernest Ezra Mandel (; 5 April 1923 – 20 July 1995), also known by various pseudonyms such as Ernest Germain, Pierre Gousset, Henri Vallin, Walter, was a Belgian Marxian economist, Trotskyist activist and theorist, and Holocaust survivor. He f ...
Ben Fine
Ben Fine (born 1948) is Professor of Economics at the University of London's School of Oriental and African Studies.
Background
Fine was born in Coventry in 1948. One of six brothers, he and all but one other followed their father and studied m ...
Paul Cockshott
William Paul Cockshott (born 16 March 1952) is a Scottish academic in the fields of computer science and Marxist economics. He is a Reader at the University of Glasgow. Since 1993 he has authored multiple works in the tradition of scientif ...
, Gregory John Michaelson & Victor Yakovenko,
Michael Heinrich
Michael Heinrich (born 1957) is a German historian of philosophy and political scientist, specialising in the critical study of the development of Karl Marx's thought. Heinrich's work, influenced by Elmar Altvater and the Neue Marx-Lektüre of ...
, and Bill Jefferies.
The future
Modern digital technology enables digitally skilled individuals to set up their own business, producing digital products and services, with a relatively low capital outlay. Therefore, "simple commodity production" could turn out to be not an outdated economic category of the past, but a common sort of work in the future.
Karl Marx
Karl Marx (; 5 May 1818 – 14 March 1883) was a German philosopher, political theorist, economist, journalist, and revolutionary socialist. He is best-known for the 1848 pamphlet '' The Communist Manifesto'' (written with Friedrich Engels) ...
regarded piece-wages as “the form of wage most appropriate to the capitalist mode of production”, and he noted that with piece-work – characteristic of domestic labour schemes and cottage industries – the “superintendence of labour becomes to a great extent superfluous”, which can be a significant cost-saving. He also noted, that piece-work can be carried out not just by individual workers, but also collectively by groups of ''self-managed'' workers – via various forms of contracting and subcontracting, where the buyer of the products pays only for the outputs supplied by the group. Labour historian Jan Lucassen has shown that this practice has a very lengthy history, which goes right back to the brickmakers of
Babylon
Babylon ( ) was an ancient city located on the lower Euphrates river in southern Mesopotamia, within modern-day Hillah, Iraq, about south of modern-day Baghdad. Babylon functioned as the main cultural and political centre of the Akkadian-s ...
.Jan Lucassen, ''Outlines of a history of labour''. Amsterdam: IISH-Research Paper 51, 201 /ref>