HOME

TheInfoList



OR:

In
mathematics Mathematics is an area of knowledge that includes the topics of numbers, formulas and related structures, shapes and the spaces in which they are contained, and quantities and their changes. These topics are represented in modern mathematics ...
, majorization is a
preorder In mathematics, especially in order theory, a preorder or quasiorder is a binary relation that is reflexive and transitive. Preorders are more general than equivalence relations and (non-strict) partial orders, both of which are special c ...
on vectors of
real numbers In mathematics, a real number is a number that can be used to measure a ''continuous'' one-dimensional quantity such as a distance, duration or temperature. Here, ''continuous'' means that values can have arbitrarily small variations. Every real ...
. Let ^_,\ i=1,\,\ldots,\,n denote the i-th largest element of the vector \mathbf\in\mathbb^n. Given \mathbf,\ \mathbf \in \mathbb^n, we say that \mathbf weakly majorizes (or dominates) \mathbf from below (or equivalently, we say that \mathbf is weakly majorized (or dominated) by \mathbf from below) denoted as \mathbf \succ_w \mathbf if \sum_^k x_^ \geq \sum_^k y_^ for all k=1,\,\dots,\,d. If in addition \sum_^d x_i^ = \sum_^d y_i^, we say that \mathbf majorizes (or dominates) \mathbf , written as \mathbf \succ \mathbf , or equivalently, we say that \mathbf is majorized (or dominated) by \mathbf. The order of the entries of the vectors \mathbf or \mathbf does not affect the majorization, e.g., the statement (1,2)\prec (0,3) is simply equivalent to (2,1)\prec (3,0). As a consequence, majorization is not a partial order, since \mathbf \succ \mathbf and \mathbf \succ \mathbf do not imply \mathbf = \mathbf , it only implies that the components of each vector are equal, but not necessarily in the same order. The majorization partial order on finite dimensional vectors, described here, can be generalized to the Lorenz ordering, a partial order on distribution functions. For example, a wealth distribution is Lorenz-greater than another if its Lorenz curve lies below the other. As such, a Lorenz-greater wealth distribution has a higher Gini coefficient, and has more income disparity. Various other generalizations of majorization are discussed in chapters 14 and 15 of.


Examples

(Strong) majorization: (1,2,3)\prec (0,3,3)\prec (0,0,6). For vectors with n components : \left(\frac, \ldots, \frac\right)\prec \left(\frac, \ldots, \frac,0\right) \prec \cdots \prec \left(\frac,\frac, 0, \ldots, 0\right) \prec \left(1, 0, \ldots, 0\right). (Weak) majorization: (1,2,3)\prec_w (1,3,3)\prec_w (1,3,4). For vectors with n components: : \left(\frac, \ldots, \frac\right)\prec_w \left(\frac, \ldots, \frac,1\right).


Geometry of majorization

For \mathbf,\ \mathbf \in \mathbb^n, we have \mathbf \prec \mathbf if and only if \mathbf is in the convex hull of all vectors obtained by permuting the coordinates of \mathbf. Figure 1 displays the convex hull in 2D for the vector \mathbf=(3,\,1). Notice that the center of the convex hull, which is an interval in this case, is the vector \mathbf=(2,\,2). This is the "smallest" vector satisfying \mathbf \prec \mathbf for this given vector \mathbf. Figure 2 shows the convex hull in 3D. The center of the convex hull, which is a 2D polygon in this case, is the "smallest" vector \mathbf satisfying \mathbf \prec \mathbf for this given vector \mathbf.


Schur convexity

A function f:\mathbb^n \to \mathbb is said to be Schur convex when \mathbf \succ \mathbf implies f(\mathbf) \geq f(\mathbf). Hence, Schur-convex functions translate the ordering of vectors to a standard ordering in \mathbb. Similarly, f(\mathbf) is Schur concave when \mathbf \succ \mathbf implies f(\mathbf) \leq f(\mathbf). An example of a Schur-convex function is the max function, \max(\mathbf)=x_^. Schur convex functions are necessarily symmetric that the entries of it argument can be switched without modifying the value of the function. Therefore, linear functions, which are convex, are not Schur-convex unless they are symmetric. If a function is symmetric and convex, then it is Schur-convex.


Equivalent conditions

Each of the following statements is true if and only if \mathbf\succ \mathbf: * \mathbf = \mathbf\mathbf for some doubly stochastic matrix \mathbf.Barry C. Arnold. "Majorization and the Lorenz Order: A Brief Introduction". Springer-Verlag Lecture Notes in Statistics, vol. 43, 1987. This is equivalent to saying \mathbf can be represented as a convex combination of the permutations of \mathbf; one can verify that there exists such a convex representation using at most n permutations of \mathbf. * From \mathbf we can produce \mathbf by a finite sequence of "Robin Hood operations" where we replace two elements x_i and x_j < x_i with x_i-\varepsilon and x_j+\varepsilon, respectively, for some \varepsilon \in (0, x_i-x_j). * For every convex function h:\mathbb\to \mathbb, \sum_^d h(x_i) \geq \sum_^d h(y_i). **In fact, a special case suffices: \sum_i=\sum_i and, for every , \sum_^d \max(0,x_i-t) \geq\sum_^d \max(0,y_i-t).July 3, 2005 post by fleeting_guest o
"The Karamata Inequality" thread
AoPS community forums.
Archived
11 November 2020.
* \forall t \in \mathbb \quad \sum_^d , x_j-t, \geq \sum_^d , y_j-t, .


In linear algebra

* Suppose that for two real vectors \mathbf,\ \mathbf \in \mathbb^d, \mathbf majorizes \mathbf. Then it can be shown that there exists a set of probabilities (p_1,p_2,\ldots,p_d),\ \sum_^d p_i=1 and a set of
permutation In mathematics, a permutation of a set is, loosely speaking, an arrangement of its members into a sequence or linear order, or if the set is already ordered, a rearrangement of its elements. The word "permutation" also refers to the act or proc ...
s (P_1,P_2,\ldots,P_d) such that \mathbf=\sum_^d p_iP_i\mathbf. Alternatively it can be shown that there exists a doubly stochastic matrix \mathbf such that \mathbf\mathbf=\mathbf *We say that a Hermitian operator, \mathbf, majorizes another, \mathbf, if the set of eigenvalues of \mathbf majorizes that of \mathbf.


In computability theory

Given f, \ g : \mathbb \to\mathbb, then f is said to ''majorize'' g if, for all x, f(x)\geq g(x). If there is some n so that f(x)\geq g(x) for all x > n, then f is said to ''dominate'' (or ''eventually dominate'') g. Alternatively, the preceding terms are often defined requiring the strict inequality f(x) > g(x) instead of f(x)\geq g(x) in the foregoing definitions.


See also

* Muirhead's inequality * Karamata's Inequality *
Schur-convex function In mathematics, a Schur-convex function, also known as S-convex, isotonic function and order-preserving function is a function f: \mathbb^d\rightarrow \mathbb that for all x,y\in \mathbb^d such that x is majorized by y, one has that f(x)\le f(y). ...
*
Schur–Horn theorem In mathematics, particularly linear algebra, the Schur–Horn theorem, named after Issai Schur and Alfred Horn, characterizes the diagonal of a Hermitian matrix with given eigenvalues. It has inspired investigations and substantial generalizations ...
relating diagonal entries of a matrix to its eigenvalues. * For positive integer numbers, weak majorization is called Dominance order. * Leximin order


Notes


References

* J. Karamata. "Sur une inegalite relative aux fonctions convexes." ''Publ. Math. Univ. Belgrade'' 1, 145–158, 1932. * G. H. Hardy, J. E. Littlewood and G. Pólya, ''Inequalities'', 2nd edition, 1952, Cambridge University Press, London. * ''Inequalities: Theory of Majorization and Its Applications'' Albert W. Marshall, Ingram Olkin, Barry Arnold, Second edition. Springer Series in Statistics. Springer, New York, 2011.
A tribute to Marshall and Olkin's book "Inequalities: Theory of Majorization and its Applications"
* ''Matrix Analysis'' (1996) Rajendra Bhatia, Springer, * ''Topics in Matrix Analysis'' (1994) Roger A. Horn and Charles R. Johnson, Cambridge University Press, * ''Majorization and Matrix Monotone Functions in Wireless Communications'' (2007) Eduard Jorswieck and Holger Boche, Now Publishers, * ''The Cauchy Schwarz Master Class'' (2004) J. Michael Steele, Cambridge University Press, {{ISBN, 978-0-521-54677-5


External links






Software

*
OCTAVE In music, an octave ( la, octavus: eighth) or perfect octave (sometimes called the diapason) is the interval between one musical pitch and another with double its frequency. The octave relationship is a natural phenomenon that has been refer ...
/ MATLABbr>code to check majorization
Order theory Linear algebra