Lindahl Equilibrium
   HOME

TheInfoList



OR:

A Lindahl tax is a form of
taxation A tax is a mandatory financial charge or levy imposed on an individual or legal person, legal entity by a governmental organization to support government spending and public expenditures collectively or to Pigouvian tax, regulate and reduce nega ...
conceived by
Erik Lindahl Erik Lindahl (21 November 1891 – 6 January 1960) was a Swedish economist. He was professor of economics at Uppsala University 1942–58 and in 1956–59 he was the President of the International Economic Association. He was an also an advis ...
in which individuals pay for
public good In economics, a public good (also referred to as a social good or collective good)Oakland, W. H. (1987). Theory of public goods. In Handbook of public economics (Vol. 2, pp. 485–535). Elsevier. is a commodity, product or service that is bo ...
s according to their
marginal benefit Marginal utility, in mainstream economics, describes the change in ''utility'' (pleasure or satisfaction resulting from the consumption) of one unit of a good or service. Marginal utility can be positive, negative, or zero. Negative marginal utilit ...
s. In other words, they pay according to the amount of satisfaction or
utility In economics, utility is a measure of a certain person's satisfaction from a certain state of the world. Over time, the term has been used with at least two meanings. * In a normative context, utility refers to a goal or objective that we wish ...
they derive from the consumption of an additional unit of the public good. Lindahl taxation is designed to maximize
efficiency Efficiency is the often measurable ability to avoid making mistakes or wasting materials, energy, efforts, money, and time while performing a task. In a more general sense, it is the ability to do things well, successfully, and without waste. ...
for each individual and provide the optimal level of a public good. Lindahl taxes can be seen as an individual's share of the collective
tax burden In economics, tax incidence or tax burden is the effect of a particular tax on the distribution of economic welfare. Economists distinguish between the entities who ultimately bear the tax burden and those on whom the tax is initially imposed. The ...
of an economy. The optimal level of a public good is that quantity at which the
willingness to pay In behavioral economics, willingness to pay (WTP) is the maximum price at or below which a consumer will definitely buy one unit of a product. This corresponds to the standard economic view of a consumer reservation price. Some researchers, ho ...
for one more unit of the good, taken in totality for all the individuals is equal to the
marginal cost In economics, the marginal cost is the change in the total cost that arises when the quantity produced is increased, i.e. the cost of producing additional quantity. In some contexts, it refers to an increment of one unit of output, and in others it ...
of supplying that good. Lindahl tax is the optimal quantity times the willingness to pay for one more unit of that good at this quantity.''Equity: In Theory and Practice''
p. 103.


History

The idea of using aggregate
marginal utility Marginal utility, in mainstream economics, describes the change in ''utility'' (pleasure or satisfaction resulting from the consumption) of one unit of a good or service. Marginal utility can be positive, negative, or zero. Negative marginal utilit ...
in the analysis of public finance was not new in Europe.
Knut Wicksell Johan Gustaf Knut Wicksell (December 20, 1851 – May 3, 1926) was a Swedish economist of the Stockholm school. He was professor at Uppsala University and Lund University. He made contributions to theories of population, value, capital and mon ...
was one of the most prominent economists who studied this concept, eventually arguing that no individual should be forced to pay for any activity that does not give them utility.
Erik Lindahl Erik Lindahl (21 November 1891 – 6 January 1960) was a Swedish economist. He was professor of economics at Uppsala University 1942–58 and in 1956–59 he was the President of the International Economic Association. He was an also an advis ...
was deeply influenced by Wicksell, who was his professor and mentor, and proposed a method for financing public goods in order to show that consensus politics is possible. As people are different in nature, their preferences are different, and consensus requires each individual to pay a somewhat different tax for every service, or good that he consumes. If each person's tax price is set equal to the marginal benefits received at the ideal service level, each person is made better off by provision of the public good and may accordingly agree to have that service level provided.


Lindahl equilibrium

A Lindahl equilibrium is a state of
economic equilibrium In economics, economic equilibrium is a situation in which the economic forces of supply and demand are balanced, meaning that economic variables will no longer change. Market equilibrium in this case is a condition where a market price is es ...
under a Lindahl tax as well as a method for finding the optimum level for the supply of public goods or services that happens when the total per-unit price paid by each individual equals the total per-unit cost of the public good. It can be shown that an equilibrium exists for different environments.Mark Walker
"Lindahl Equilibrium"
University of Arizona
Therefore, the Lindahl equilibrium describes how efficiency can be sustained in an economy with personalized prices.
Leif Johansen Leif Johansen (11 May 1930 – 29 December 1982) was a Norwegian economist who made a substantial contribution to economic science. He was born in Eidsvoll. Throughout his academic career Johansen was employed at the University of Oslo. He was a ...
gave the complete interpretation of the concept of "Lindahl equilibrium", which assumes that household consumption decisions are based on the share of the cost they must provide for the supply of the particular public good. This method of taxation for public goods is an equilibrium for two reasons. First, individuals are willing to pay the respective taxes for the quantity of public goods provided. Second, the cost of the public good is covered by the aggregate taxes. Therefore, the Lindahl pricing centers around the
benefit principle The benefit principle is a concept in the theory of taxation from public finance. It bases taxes to pay for public-goods expenditures on a politically-revealed willingness to pay for benefits received. The principle is sometimes likened to the ...
, in which individuals are taxed based on their valuation of the benefit received from the good. This equilibrium is also the efficient level of public goods, as the social marginal benefit is equivalent to the social marginal cost. The importance of Lindahl equilibrium is that it fulfills the
Samuelson condition The Samuelson condition, due to Paul Samuelson, in the theory of public economics, is a condition for optimal provision of public goods. For an economy with ''n'' consumers, the conditions is: : \sum_^n \text_i = \text MRS''i'' is individual ' ...
and is therefore
Pareto efficient In welfare economics, a Pareto improvement formalizes the idea of an outcome being "better in every possible way". A change is called a Pareto improvement if it leaves at least one person in society better off without leaving anyone else worse ...
, despite the good in question being a public one. It also demonstrates how
efficiency Efficiency is the often measurable ability to avoid making mistakes or wasting materials, energy, efforts, money, and time while performing a task. In a more general sense, it is the ability to do things well, successfully, and without waste. ...
can be reached in an economy with public goods by the use of personalized prices. The personalized prices equate the individual valuation for a public good to the cost of the public good.


Lindahl equilibrium in an economy with only a public good

Lindahl and Samuelson defined the Lindahl equilibrium in a general economy, in which there are both public and private goods. Fain,
Goel Goel or Goyal (alternative transliterations of Hindi गोयलl) is a surname of Indian origin. It may refer to: Goel * Adarsh Kumar Goel (born 1953), Indian judge * Anita Goel, American physicist, physician, and scientist * Aseem Goel, In ...
and Mungala. Note that what they call "core" is often called the "weak core". present a specialized definition, for the case in which there are only public goods. * There is a fixed budget ''B'', and ''k'' types of divisible public goods. * The goal is to decide on an allocation x of the budget, such that x1+...+xk = B. * There are ''n'' agents; each agent ''i'' has a utility function ''Ui'' over possible allocations of the budget. An allocation x is a Lindahl equilibrium if there exist personal price-vectors p1,...,pn such that the following two conditions hold: # For every agent ''i'', the allocation x maximizes the utility ''Ui''(x) subject to \mathbf\cdot \mathbf \leq B/n . That is: x is the best bundle that agent ''i'' could buy with his proportional share of the budget and his personal prices. In other words: if each agent chooses the best public bundle he can afford given his personal prices, then all agents unanimously choose ''the same'' public bundle. # The allocation x maximizes the ''profit'', defined as \sum_^n \mathbf\cdot \mathbf - , \mathbf, _1 . Intuitively, it is assumed that some producer can produce public goods in cost 1, and he sells them to the public; his profit is the total amount of money he gains from selling the goods in the given prices, minus the total cost of production. The personalized price-vector pi can be interpreted as the Lindahl tax on agent ''i''. Note the difference from a
competitive equilibrium Competitive equilibrium (also called: Walrasian equilibrium) is a concept of economic equilibrium, introduced by Kenneth Arrow and Gérard Debreu in 1951, appropriate for the analysis of commodity markets with flexible prices and many traders, and ...
in a market of private goods (
Fisher market Fisher market is an economic model attributed to Irving Fisher. It has the following ingredients: * A set of m divisible products with pre-specified supplies (usually normalized such that the supply of each good is 1). * A set of n buyers. * For eac ...
): * In a Fisher market equilibrium, there is a single price-vector for all agents, but each agent has a different bundle * In a Lindahl equilibrium, there is a personal price-vector for each agent, but all agents have the same bundle. A Lindahl equilibrium allocation in a market of public goods has a characterization without the price-vectors. Specifically, an allocation x is a Lindahl equilibrium if and only if, for every good ''j'', \sum_^n \frac \leq \frac , where the inequality becomes an equality when x_j>0 .


Existence

Foley proved that, If the utility functions have continuous derivatives, are strictly increasing, and are strictly concave, then a Lindahl equilibrium exists in the general case of mixed public and private goods, and moreover, it lies in the fractional
core Core or cores may refer to: Science and technology * Core (anatomy), everything except the appendages * Core (laboratory), a highly specialized shared research resource * Core (manufacturing), used in casting and molding * Core (optical fiber ...
. However, his proof is existential and does not provide an efficient algorithm.


Manipulation

The mechanism that, given agents' utilities, computes the Lindahl equilibrium, is not
strategyproof In mechanism design, a strategyproof (SP) mechanism is a game form in which each player has a weakly-dominant strategy, so that no player can gain by "spying" over the other players to know what they are going to play. When the players have private ...
, even in the setting with only public goods. This is a special case of the
free-rider problem In economics, the free-rider problem is a type of market failure that occurs when those who benefit from resources, public goods and common pool resources do not pay for them or under-pay. Free riders may overuse common pool resources by not ...
.


Computation

Fain,
Goel Goel or Goyal (alternative transliterations of Hindi गोयलl) is a surname of Indian origin. It may refer to: Goel * Adarsh Kumar Goel (born 1953), Indian judge * Anita Goel, American physicist, physician, and scientist * Aseem Goel, In ...
and Mungala present an algorithm for computing the Lindahl equilibrium using
convex programming Convex optimization is a subfield of mathematical optimization that studies the problem of minimizing convex functions over convex sets (or, equivalently, maximizing concave functions over convex sets). Many classes of convex optimization problem ...
, in the special case in which agents have ''scalar-separable'' ''non-satiating utilities''. Particularly: * If the agents' utilities are homogeneous of degree 1 and
concave Concave or concavity may refer to: Science and technology * Concave lens * Concave mirror Mathematics * Concave function, the negative of a convex function * Concave polygon A simple polygon that is not convex is called concave, non-convex or ...
, the Lindahl equilibrium allocation can be computed by maxizing the Nash welfare \sum_^n \log U_i(\mathbf) . Moreover, the gradient of this objective function can be computed using
quadratic voting Quadratic voting (QV) is a voting system that encourages voters to express their true relative intensity of preference (utility) between multiple options or elections. By doing so, quadratic voting seeks to mitigate tyranny of the majority—wher ...
. * For more general non-satiating utility functions, the Lindahl equilibrium can be computed by maximizing a potential function, that can be seen as a regularized version of the Nash welfare.


Discrete Lindahl equilibrium

Peters, PIerczynski, Shah and Skowron present an adaptation of the concept of Lindahl equilibrium to a market with ''indivisible'' public goods. In this setting, a Lindahl equilibrium may be not
Pareto-efficient In welfare economics, a Pareto improvement formalizes the idea of an outcome being "better in every possible way". A change is called a Pareto improvement if it leaves at least one person in society better off without leaving anyone else worse ...
. * Example: there are three goods (a, b1, b2) and two voters, where Alice values a, b1 at 1 and b2 at 0, and George values a, b2 at 1 and b1 at 0. The budget of each agent is 3, and the cost of each good is 2. Producing only is a Lindahl equilibrium, with prices for Alice: 2-0.009, 2-0.006, 0.001 and prices for George: 2-0.009, 0.001, 2-0.006. This is because (1) it maximizes the profit: the producer would not gain from producing b1 or b2; (2) it maximizes the agents' utilities: no agent can afford another desirable good. But is not efficient, since it is dominated by . If the definition is strengthened to require that the total payment for each public good exactly equals its cost, then the stronger Lindahl equilibrium notion is equivalent to a concept they call ''strict stable priceability''. A stable-priceable committee does not always exist, but extensive simulation experiments show that an "almost" stable-priceable committee almost always exists. It is possible to check in polynomial time whether a given committee is stable-priceable.


Lindahl Model

In the Lindahl Model, Dt represents the aggregate marginal benefit curve, which is the sum of Da and Db---the marginal benefits for the two individuals in the economy. In a Lindahl equilibrium, the optimal quantity of the public good will be where the social marginal benefit intersects the marginal cost (point P). Each individual's Lindahl tax rate will be based on their own marginal benefit curve. In this model, individual B will pay the price level at R and individual A will pay at point J.


Criticism

In theory, Lindahl pricing and taxation leads to an efficient provision of public goods. However, it requires the knowledge of the demand functions for each individual, and therefore is difficult to implement in practice. There are three main problems with the implementation of a Lindahl tax.


Preference revelation problem

When information about marginal benefits is available only from the individuals themselves, they tend to under report their valuation for a particular good. In doing this, an individual can lower his or her tax cost by under reporting the benefits derived from the public good or service. The incentive to lie is associated with the free rider problem; if an individual reports a lower benefit, he or she will pay less taxes, but only see a marginal decrease in the public good. This informational problem shows that survey-based Lindahl taxation is not
incentive compatible In game theory and economics, a mechanism is called incentive-compatible (IC) if every participant can achieve their own best outcome by reporting their true preferences. For example, there is incentive compatibility if high-risk clients are bette ...
. Incentives to understate or under report one's true benefits under Lindahl taxation resemble those of a traditional
public goods game The public goods game is a standard of experimental economics. In the basic game, subjects Information asymmetry, secretly choose how many of their Private good, private tokens to put into a public pot. The payoff of each player is her "private co ...
. Preference revelation mechanisms can be used to solve that problem,"Fred Foldvary on Demand Revelation: Better than Voting"
although none of these has been shown to completely and satisfactorily address it. The
Vickrey–Clarke–Groves mechanism In mechanism design, the Vickrey–Clarke–Groves (VCG) mechanism is a generic truthful mechanism for achieving a socially optimal solution whenever monetary transfers are available. It generalizes the Vickrey–Clarke–Groves auction into a ge ...
is an example of this, ensuring true values are revealed and that a public good is provided only when it should be. The allocation of cost is taken as given and the consumers will report their net benefits (benefits-cost) the public good will be provided if the sum of the net benefits of all consumers is positive. If the public good is provided side payments will be made reflecting the fact that truth telling is costly. The side payments internalize the net benefit of the public good to other players. The side payments must be financed from outside the mechanism. In reality, preference revelation is difficult as the size of the population makes it costly both in terms of money and time.


Preference knowledge problem

A second drawback to the Lindahl solution is that individuals may be unsure of their own valuation of a public good. Even if individuals are attempting to be honest with their willingness to pay, they may have no idea of their true value. This is especially true for public goods that individuals do not interact with on a day-to-day basis, like fireworks and national defense.


Preference aggregation problem

Even if individuals know their marginal willingness to pay, and are honest in their reporting, the government can have extreme difficulties aggregating this into a social value. In situations where few individuals are affected by the public good, like the example below, aggregation can be relatively simple. However, in the case of national defense in the United States, compiling the marginal willingness to pay for this public good of each individual would be nearly impossible.


Mathematical representation

We assume that there are two goods in an economy:the first one is a "public good", and the second is "everything else". The price of the public good can be assumed to be ''Ppublic'' and the price of everything else can be ''Pelse''. Person 1 will choose his bundle such that: * ''α*P(public)/P(else) = MRS(person1)'' This is just the usual price ratio/
marginal rate of substitution In economics, the marginal rate of substitution (MRS) is the rate at which a consumer can give up some amount of one good in exchange for another good while maintaining the same level of utility. At equilibrium consumption levels (assuming no ext ...
deal; the only change is that we multiply ''Ppublic'' by α to allow for the price adjustment to the public good. Similarly, Person 2 will choose his bundle such that: * ''(1-ɑ)*P(public)/P(else)= MRS(person2)'' Now we have both individuals' utility maximizing. We know that in a competitive equilibrium, the marginal cost ratio or price ratio should be equal to the marginal rate of transformation, or * ''MC(public)/MC(else)= (public)/P(else)MRT''


Example

Take for example a public park, with a constant marginal cost of $15 per acre. This public park will be available to two people, Sarah and Tom. Figure 1 shows Sarah's marginal willingness to pay for a public park. For the first acre of the park, Sarah is willing to pay $20. For the 80th acre, her marginal willingness to pay has decreased down to zero. Figure 2 shows Tom's marginal willingness to pay for a public park. Unlike Sarah, for the first acre of park he is willing to pay $40, and for the 40th acre of park he has a marginal willingness to pay of $20. For the 80th acre of park his marginal willingness to pay is zero. Figure 3 shows the aggregate marginal willingness to pay for the public park. As seen on the figure, Sarah and Tom together are willing to pay $60 for the first acre of park. This is higher than the marginal cost of the first acre ($15) and therefore this first acre of park should be produced. Sarah and Tom together are willing to pay $45 for the 20th acre, and $30 for the 40th acre, which are both again above the marginal cost of $15. The marginal cost curve intersects their aggregate willingness to pay curve at the 60th acre, when they are together willing to pay the $15 marginal cost. Thus, the Lindahl equilibrium involves charging Sarah $5 and Tom $10 for each of the 60 acres of park.


See also

*
Benefit principle The benefit principle is a concept in the theory of taxation from public finance. It bases taxes to pay for public-goods expenditures on a politically-revealed willingness to pay for benefits received. The principle is sometimes likened to the ...
*
Public choice theory Public choice, or public choice theory, is "the use of economic tools to deal with traditional problems of political science." Gordon Tullock, 9872008, "public choice," '' The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics''. . It includes the study of ...
*
Public finance Public finance refers to the monetary resources available to governments and also to the study of finance within government and role of the government in the economy. Within academic settings, public finance is a widely studied subject in man ...
*
Samuelson condition The Samuelson condition, due to Paul Samuelson, in the theory of public economics, is a condition for optimal provision of public goods. For an economy with ''n'' consumers, the conditions is: : \sum_^n \text_i = \text MRS''i'' is individual ' ...
*
Value capture Value capture is a type of public financing that recovers some or all of the value that public infrastructure generates for private landowners. In many countries, the public sector is responsible for the infrastructure required to support urban dev ...


Sources


Citations


References and further reading

* .
"Public Economics" by Gareth D. Myles (October 2001)
* * . * *


External links

* * https://web.archive.org/web/20050506100038/http://dept.econ.yorku.ca/~sam/4080/pub_goods/4.pdf {{Microeconomics, state=collapsed Theory of taxation