Party-list proportional representation
Apportionment methods
The quota or divide-and-rank methods make up a category of
apportionment rules, i.e. algorithms for allocating seats in a legislative body among multiple groups (e.g.
parties or
federal states). The quota methods begin by calculating an
entitlement (basic number of seats) for each party, by dividing their vote totals by an
electoral quota
In proportional representation systems, an electoral quota is the number of votes a candidate needs to be guaranteed election. They are used in some systems where a formula other than plurality is used to allocate seats.
Generally quotas are set ...
(a fixed number of votes needed to win a seat, as a unit). Then, leftover seats, if any are allocated by rounding up the apportionment for some parties. These rules are typically contrasted with the more popular
highest averages methods (also called divisor methods).
By far the most common quota method are the largest remainders or quota-shift methods, which assign any leftover seats to the "plurality" winners (the parties with the largest
remainders, i.e. most leftover votes).
When using the
Hare quota
The Hare quota (sometimes called the simple, ideal, or Hamilton quota) is the number of voters represented by each legislator in an idealized system of proportional representation where every vote is used to elect someone. The Hare quota is eq ...
, this rule is called
Hamilton's method, and is the third-most common apportionment rule worldwide (after
Jefferson's method and
Webster's method).
Despite their intuitive definition, quota methods are generally disfavored by
social choice theorists as a result of
apportionment paradoxes.
In particular, the largest remainder methods exhibit the
no-show paradox
The participation criterion is a Comparison of electoral systems, voting system criterion that says candidates should never lose an election as a result of receiving too many votes in support. More formally, it says that adding more voters who pre ...
, i.e. voting ''for'' a party can cause it to ''lose'' seats.
The largest remainders methods are also vulnerable to
spoiler effects and can fail
resource
''Resource'' refers to all the materials available in our environment which are Technology, technologically accessible, Economics, economically feasible and Culture, culturally Sustainability, sustainable and help us to satisfy our needs and want ...
or
house monotonicity, which says that increasing the number of seats in a legislature should not cause a party to lose a seat (a situation known as an
Alabama paradox).
Method
The largest remainder method divides each party's vote total by a ''quota''. Usually, quota is derived by dividing the number of valid votes cast, by the number of seats. The result for each party will consist of an
integer
An integer is the number zero (0), a positive natural number (1, 2, 3, ...), or the negation of a positive natural number (−1, −2, −3, ...). The negations or additive inverses of the positive natural numbers are referred to as negative in ...
part plus a
fractional remainder
In mathematics, the remainder is the amount "left over" after performing some computation. In arithmetic, the remainder is the integer "left over" after dividing one integer by another to produce an integer quotient ( integer division). In a ...
. Each party is first allocated a number of seats equal to their integer. This will generally leave some remainder seats unallocated. To apportion these seats, the parties are then ranked on the basis of their fractional remainders, and the parties with the largest remainders are each allocated one additional seat until all seats have been allocated. This gives the method its name - largest remainder.
Largest remainder methods produces similar results to
single transferable vote
The single transferable vote (STV) or proportional-ranked choice voting (P-RCV) is a multi-winner electoral system in which each voter casts a single vote in the form of a ranked ballot. Voters have the option to rank candidates, and their vot ...
or the
quota Borda system, where voters organize themselves into
solid coalitions. The
single transferable vote
The single transferable vote (STV) or proportional-ranked choice voting (P-RCV) is a multi-winner electoral system in which each voter casts a single vote in the form of a ranked ballot. Voters have the option to rank candidates, and their vot ...
or the
quota Borda system behave like the largest-remainders method when voters all behave like strict partisans (i.e. only mark preferences for candidates of one party).
Quotas
There are several possible choices for the
electoral quota
In proportional representation systems, an electoral quota is the number of votes a candidate needs to be guaranteed election. They are used in some systems where a formula other than plurality is used to allocate seats.
Generally quotas are set ...
. The choice of quota affects the properties of the corresponding largest remainder method, and particularly the
seat bias. Smaller quotas allow small parties to pick up seats, while larger quotas leave behind more votes. A somewhat counterintuitive result of this is that a ''larger'' quota will always be more favorable to ''smaller'' parties. A party hoping to win multiple seats sees fewer votes captured by a single popular candidate when the quota is small.
The two most common quotas are the
Hare quota
The Hare quota (sometimes called the simple, ideal, or Hamilton quota) is the number of voters represented by each legislator in an idealized system of proportional representation where every vote is used to elect someone. The Hare quota is eq ...
and the
Droop quota
In the study of Electoral system, electoral systems, the Droop quota (sometimes called the Eduard Hagenbach-Bischoff, Hagenbach-Bischoff, Britton, or Newland-Britton quota) is the Infimum, minimum number of votes a party or candidate needs to rece ...
. The use of a particular quota with one of the largest remainder methods is often abbreviated as "LR-
uota name, such as "LR-Droop".
The Hare (or simple) quota is defined as follows:
:
LR-Hare is sometimes called Hamilton's method, named after
Alexander Hamilton
Alexander Hamilton (January 11, 1755 or 1757July 12, 1804) was an American military officer, statesman, and Founding Fathers of the United States, Founding Father who served as the first U.S. secretary of the treasury from 1789 to 1795 dur ...
, who devised the method in 1792.
The
Droop quota
In the study of Electoral system, electoral systems, the Droop quota (sometimes called the Eduard Hagenbach-Bischoff, Hagenbach-Bischoff, Britton, or Newland-Britton quota) is the Infimum, minimum number of votes a party or candidate needs to rece ...
is given by:
:
and is applied to elections in
South Africa
South Africa, officially the Republic of South Africa (RSA), is the Southern Africa, southernmost country in Africa. Its Provinces of South Africa, nine provinces are bounded to the south by of coastline that stretches along the Atlantic O ...
.
The Hare quota is more generous to less-popular parties and the Droop quota to more-popular parties. Specifically, the Hare quota is
''unbiased'' in the number of seats it hands out, and so is more proportional than the Droop quota (which tends to give more seats to larger parties). The Hare suffers the disproportionality that it sometimes allocates a majority of seats to a party with less than a majority of votes in a district.
Examples
The following example allocates 11 seats using the largest-remainder method by Droop quota.
Pros and cons
It is easy for a voter to understand how the largest remainder method allocates seats. Moreover, the largest remainder method satisfies the
quota rule (each party's seats are equal to its ideal share of seats, either rounded up or rounded down) and was designed to satisfy that criterion. However, this comes at the cost of greater inequalities in the
seats-to-votes ratio, which can violate the principle of
one man, one vote.
However, a greater concern for social choice theorists, and the primary cause behind its abandonment in many countries, is the tendency of such rules to produce erratic or irrational behaviors called
apportionment paradoxes:
* ''Increasing'' the number of seats in a legislature can ''decrease'' a party's apportionment of seats, called the
Alabama paradox.
* Adding more parties to the legislature can cause a bizarre kind of
spoiler effect called the
new state paradox.
** When Congress first admitted
Oklahoma
Oklahoma ( ; Choctaw language, Choctaw: , ) is a landlocked U.S. state, state in the South Central United States, South Central region of the United States. It borders Texas to the south and west, Kansas to the north, Missouri to the northea ...
to the Union, the House was expanded by 5 seats, equal to Oklahoma's apportionment, to ensure it would not affect the seats for any existing states. However, when the full apportionment was recalculated, the House was stunned to learn Oklahoma's entry had caused New York to lose a seat to Maine, despite there being no change in either state's population.
** By the same token, apportionments may depend on the precise order in which the apportionment is calculated. For example, identifying winning independents first and electing them, then apportioning the remaining seats, will produce a different result from treating each independent as if they were their own party and then computing a single overall apportionment.
Such paradoxes also have the additional drawback of making it difficult or impossible to generalize procedure to more complex apportionment problems such as
biproportional apportionments or
partial vote linkage. This is in part responsible for the extreme complexity of administering elections by quota-based rules like the single transferable vote (see
counting single transferable votes
The single transferable vote (STV) is a proportional representation system and ranked voting rule that elects multiple winners. Under STV, an elector's vote is initially allocated to their first-ranked candidate. Candidates are elected (''winner ...
).
Alabama paradox
The
Alabama paradox is when an ''increase'' in the total number of seats leads to a ''decrease'' in the number of seats allocated to a certain party. In the example below, when the number of seats to be allocated is increased from 25 to 26, parties D and E end up with fewer seats, despite their entitlements increasing.
With 25 seats, the results are:
With 26 seats, the results are:
References
External links
Hamilton method experimentation appletat
cut-the-knot
Alexander Bogomolny (January 4, 1948 July 7, 2018) was a Soviet Union, Soviet-born Israeli Americans, Israeli-American mathematician. He was Professor Emeritus of Mathematics at the University of Iowa, and formerly research fellow at the Moscow ...
{{voting systems
Voting theory