Kinked Demand
   HOME

TheInfoList



OR:

The Kinked-Demand curve theory is an
economic theory Economics () is a behavioral science that studies the production, distribution, and consumption of goods and services. Economics focuses on the behaviour and interactions of economic agents and how economies work. Microeconomics anal ...
regarding
oligopoly An oligopoly () is a market in which pricing control lies in the hands of a few sellers. As a result of their significant market power, firms in oligopolistic markets can influence prices through manipulating the supply function. Firms in ...
and
monopolistic competition Monopolistic competition is a type of imperfect competition such that there are many producers competing against each other but selling products that are differentiated from one another (e.g., branding, quality) and hence not perfect substi ...
. Kinked demand was an initial attempt to explain sticky prices.


Theory

"Kinked" demand curves and traditional
demand curve A demand curve is a graph depicting the inverse demand function, a relationship between the price of a certain commodity (the ''y''-axis) and the quantity of that commodity that is demanded at that price (the ''x''-axis). Demand curves can be us ...
s are similar in that they are both downward-sloping. They are distinguished by a hypothesized concave bend with a discontinuity at the bend - the "kink." Therefore, the first derivative point is undefined and leads to a
jump discontinuity Continuous functions are of utmost importance in mathematics, functions and applications. However, not all Function (mathematics), functions are continuous. If a function is not continuous at a limit point (also called "accumulation point" or "clu ...
in the
marginal revenue Marginal revenue (or marginal benefit) is a central concept in microeconomics that describes the additional total revenue generated by increasing product sales by 1 unit.Bradley R. chiller, "Essentials of Economics", New York: McGraw-Hill, Inc., ...
curve. Classical economic theory assumes that a profit-maximizing producer with some
market power In economics, market power refers to the ability of a theory of the firm, firm to influence the price at which it sells a product or service by manipulating either the supply or demand of the product or service to increase economic profit. In othe ...
(either due to
oligopoly An oligopoly () is a market in which pricing control lies in the hands of a few sellers. As a result of their significant market power, firms in oligopolistic markets can influence prices through manipulating the supply function. Firms in ...
or
monopolistic competition Monopolistic competition is a type of imperfect competition such that there are many producers competing against each other but selling products that are differentiated from one another (e.g., branding, quality) and hence not perfect substi ...
) will set
marginal costs In economics, the marginal cost is the change in the total cost that arises when the quantity produced is increased, i.e. the cost of producing additional quantity. In some contexts, it refers to an increment of one unit of output, and in others it ...
equal to
marginal revenue Marginal revenue (or marginal benefit) is a central concept in microeconomics that describes the additional total revenue generated by increasing product sales by 1 unit.Bradley R. chiller, "Essentials of Economics", New York: McGraw-Hill, Inc., ...
. This idea can be envisioned graphically by the intersection of an upward-sloping marginal
cost curve In economics, a cost curve is a graph of the costs of production as a function of total quantity produced. In a free market economy, productively efficient firms optimize their production process by minimizing cost consistent with each possible ...
and a downward-sloping marginal revenue curve . In classical theory, any change in the marginal cost structure or the marginal revenue structure will be immediately reflected in a new price and/or quantity sold of the item. This result does not occur if a "kink" exists. Because of this jump discontinuity in the marginal revenue curve, marginal costs could change without necessarily changing the price or quantity.


Formulation

The two seminal papers on kinked demand were written nearly simultaneously in 1939 on both sides of the Atlantic.
Paul Sweezy Paul Marlor Sweezy (April 10, 1910 – February 27, 2004) was a Marxist economist, political activist, publisher, and founding editor of the long-running magazine ''Monthly Review''. He is best remembered for his contributions to economic theory ...
of Harvard College published "Demand Under Conditions of Oligopoly." Sweezy argued that an ordinary demand curve does not apply to
oligopoly An oligopoly () is a market in which pricing control lies in the hands of a few sellers. As a result of their significant market power, firms in oligopolistic markets can influence prices through manipulating the supply function. Firms in ...
markets and promotes a kinked demand curve. From Queen's College in
Oxford Oxford () is a City status in the United Kingdom, cathedral city and non-metropolitan district in Oxfordshire, England, of which it is the county town. The city is home to the University of Oxford, the List of oldest universities in continuou ...
, Robert Lowe Hall and Charles J. Hitch wrote "Price Theory and Business Behavior," presenting similar ideas but including more rigorous empirical testing, including a business survey of 39 respondents in the manufacturing industry. Hall and Hitch further present a hypothesis for the initial setting of prices; this explains why the "kink" in the curve is located where it is. They base this on a notion of "full cost" -
marginal cost In economics, the marginal cost is the change in the total cost that arises when the quantity produced is increased, i.e. the cost of producing additional quantity. In some contexts, it refers to an increment of one unit of output, and in others it ...
of each unit plus a percent of overhead costs or fixed costs with an additional percent added for profit. They emphasize the importance of industry tradition in history in determining this initial price, noting further, "An overwhelming majority of the entrepreneurs thought that a price based on full average cost…was the ‘right’ price, the one which ‘ought’ to be charged."


Criticism

Others such as
George Stigler George Joseph Stigler (; January 17, 1911 – December 1, 1991) was an American economist. He was the 1982 laureate in Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences and is considered a key leader of the Chicago school of economics. Early life and e ...
have argued against kinked demand. His primary opposition is summarized in a Working Paper out of the
Stanford University Leland Stanford Junior University, commonly referred to as Stanford University, is a Private university, private research university in Stanford, California, United States. It was founded in 1885 by railroad magnate Leland Stanford (the eighth ...
Economics Department by seminal authors Elmore, Kautz, Walls et al. New classical economists, led by Chicago’s
George Stigler George Joseph Stigler (; January 17, 1911 – December 1, 1991) was an American economist. He was the 1982 laureate in Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences and is considered a key leader of the Chicago school of economics. Early life and e ...
, worked to discredit the kinked demand models. Stigler first argues that the kinked demand models are not useful, as Hall and Hitch’s model only explains observed phenomenon and is not predictive. He further explains that the kinked demand analysis only suggests why prices remain sticky and does not describe the mechanism that establishes the kink and how the kink can reform once prices change. Stigler also asserts that the model is unnecessary because Chicago theory already included allowances for short-run sticky prices due to collusion, menu costs, and regulatory or bureaucratic inefficiencies in markets.


Contemporary reformulation

Game theory Game theory is the study of mathematical models of strategic interactions. It has applications in many fields of social science, and is used extensively in economics, logic, systems science and computer science. Initially, game theory addressed ...
and models of strategic interaction have largely replaced kinked demand to explain price dislocations and slowly adjusting prices. For further information see:


Reading on contemporary applications

*A Duopoly Price Game *A Theory of Dynamic Oligopoly, Price Competition, Kinked Demand Curves, and Edgeworth Cycles * Competition in the Aluminium Industry 1945-58 *The Kinked Demand Curve: A Game-Theoretic Approach V. Bhaskar "The Kinked Demand Curve: A Game-Theoretic Approach," ''International Journal of Industrial Organization'' 6, (1998): 373.


Notes

{{reflist


References

* Bhaskar, V. 1988. "The Kinked Demand Curve: A Game-Theoretic Approach" ''International Journal of Industrial Organization'' Vol. 6, pp. 373-384. * Hall, R. and Hitch, C. 1939. "Price Theory and Business Behaviour" ''Oxford Economic Papers'' Vol. 2, pp. 12-45. * Maskin, E. and Tirole, J. 1988. "A Theory of Dynamic Oligopoly, II: Price Competition, Kinked Demand Curves, and Edgeworth Cycles" ''Econometrica'' Vol. 56, pp. 571-599. * Osborne, D. 1974. "A Duopoly Price Game" ''Economica'' Vol. 41, pp. 157-175. * Peck, M. 1961. ''Competition in the Aluminium Industry: 1945-58.'' Harvard University Press, Cambridge. * Reid, G. 1981. ''The Kinked Demand Curve Analysis of Oligopoly: Theory and Evidence.'' Edinburgh University Press, Edinburgh. * Stigler, G. 1947. "The Kinky Oligopoly Demand and Rigid Prices" ''The Journal of Political Economy'' Vol. 55, pp. 432-449. * Stigler, G. 1978. "The literature of economics: the case of the kinked oligopoly demand curve" ''Economic Inquiry'' Vol. 16, pp. 185–204. * Sweezy, P. 1939. "Demand Under Conditions of Oligopoly" ''The Journal of Political Economy'' Vol. 47, pp. 568-573.


Further reading

*Bhaskar, V., S. Machin and G. Reid "Testing a Model of the Kinked Demand Curve." ''The Journal of Industrial Economics'' 39, no. 3 (March 1991): 241-254. *Borenstein, Severin. "Evolution of U.S. Airline Competition." ''The Journal of Economic Perspective''s 6, no. 2 (Spring 1992):45-73. *"Economic focus: Sticky situations," ''The Economist'', 11 November 2006, 88. *Elmore, Kautz, Walls et al."Kinked Expectations", Working Paper, Stanford University. *Greenwald, B., J.E. Stiglitz. "Keynesian, New Keynesian and New Classical Economics." ''Oxford Economic Papers'', n.s., 39, no.1 (March 1987): 119-133. *Jones, Kit. ''An Economist Among Mandarins: A biography of Robert Hall'' (1901-1988). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1994. *Meister, J. Patrick. "Oligopoly: An In-Class Economic Game." ''The Journal of Economic Education'', vol. 30, no. 4. (Autumn, 1999): 383-391. *O'Brien, D.P. ''The Classical Economists Revisited''. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2004. *Primeaux, Walter J. and Mark R. Bomball. "A Re-examination of the Kinked Oligopoly Demand Curve." ''The Journal of Political Economy'' 82, no. 4 (1974): 851-62. *Primeaux, Walter J. and Mickey C. Smith. "Pricing Patterns and the Kinky Demand Curve." ''The Journal of Law and Economics'' 19, no. 1 (1976):189-99. *Rothschild, K. W. "Price Theory and Oligopoly." ''The Economic Journal'' 57, no. 227 (September 1947): 299-320. *"Round Table on Monopolistic and Imperfect Competition." ''American Economic Review'' 27, no. 2. (June 1937): 324-326. *Sawyer, Malcolm. "Post-Keynesian and Marxian Notions of Competition: Towards a Synthesis." In ''Competition, Technology and Money: Classical and Post-Keynesian Perspectives'', ed. Mark A. Glick, 3-22. Brookfield, VT: Edward Elgar Publishing Co., 1994. *Sen, Debapriya. "The Kinked Demand Curve Revisited." ''Economics Letters'' 84 (2004):99-105. *Simon, Julian L. "A Further Test of the Kinky Oligopoly Demand Curve." ''The American Economic Review'' 59, no. 5, (1969): 971-975. *Smith, Victor E. "Note on the Kinky Oligopoly Demand Curve." ''Southern Economic Journal'' 15, no.2, (1948): 205-210. *Stein, Jerome L. ''Monetarist, Keynesian, and New Classical Economics''. Oxford: Basil Blackwell Publishing, 1982. *Managerial Economics. "G S Gupta" Demand Imperfect competition