
In
transport economics, the generalised cost is the sum of the
monetary
Money is any item or verifiable record that is generally accepted as payment for goods and services and repayment of debts, such as taxes, in a particular country or socio-economic context. The primary functions which distinguish money are: med ...
and non-monetary costs of a journey.
It is sometimes used as a basis for judgements of transit accessibility and equitable distribution of public transit resources.
Monetary (or "
out-of-pocket") costs might include a
fare
A fare is the fee paid by a passenger for use of a public transport system: rail, bus, taxi, etc. In the case of air transport, the term airfare is often used. Fare structure is the system set up to determine how much is to be paid by various p ...
on a
public transport
Public transport (also known as public transit, mass transit, or simply transit) are forms of transport available to the general public. It typically uses a fixed schedule, route and charges a fixed fare. There is no rigid definition of whic ...
journey, or the costs of
fuel
A fuel is any material that can be made to react with other substances so that it releases energy as thermal energy or to be used for work (physics), work. The concept was originally applied solely to those materials capable of releasing chem ...
,
wear and tear and any parking charge,
toll or congestion charge on a
car
A car, or an automobile, is a motor vehicle with wheels. Most definitions of cars state that they run primarily on roads, seat one to eight people, have four wheels, and mainly transport people rather than cargo. There are around one billio ...
journey.
Non-monetary costs refer to the time spent undertaking the journey. Time is converted to a money value using a
value of time figure, which usually varies according to the traveller's income and the purpose of the trip.
The generalised cost is equivalent to the price of the good in
supply and demand
In microeconomics, supply and demand is an economic model of price determination in a Market (economics), market. It postulates that, Ceteris_paribus#Applications, holding all else equal, the unit price for a particular Good (economics), good ...
theory, and so demand for journeys can be related to the generalised cost of those journeys using the
price elasticity of demand
A good's price elasticity of demand (E_d, PED) is a measure of how sensitive the quantity demanded is to its price. When the price rises, quantity demanded falls for almost any good ( law of demand), but it falls more for some than for others. Th ...
. Supply is equivalent to capacity (and, for roads, road quality) on the network.
Basic form
In a basic form, the generalised cost (g) is composed of the following:
* ''p'' refers to the monetary (out-of-pocket) costs of the journey.
* ''u(w)'' refers to the non-monetary (time) costs of an uncongested journey. This is a function of ''w'' (in the
transport economic model, ''w'' is a measure of road standard or public transport service level, both of which are related to capacity). When the free-flow journey time is known, ''u(w)'' can be calculated as the product of the journey time (''t'') in uncongested conditions and the
opportunity cost
In microeconomic theory, the opportunity cost of a choice is the value of the best alternative forgone where, given limited resources, a choice needs to be made between several mutually exclusive alternatives. Assuming the best choice is made, ...
of the traveller's time (''τ''), so that
.
Congestible networks
In a
congestible system, every traveller imposes a small delay on every other traveller, increasing the journey time for all travellers. The generalised cost function can be expanded to reflect this ''congestion delay''.
The additional term ''v(q,w)'' refers to the opportunity cost of the additional journey time a traveller experiences because of congestion. In transport economic models, the parameter ''q'' is the demand and ''w'' is a measure of capacity (which is relevant when considering possible capacity expansion).
For example, if the travel time on a particular stretch of road increases by 10 minutes for every 1000 vehicles per hour that use the road, if ''q'' were measured in thousands of vehicles per hour, we would consider the congestion function to be
.
Weighting different types of time
It has been observed that travellers prefer time spent on some parts of their journey over time spent on others. A typical journey can be divided into four parts:
* Walk from the origin
* Wait for the vehicle
* Ride in the vehicle
* Walk to the destination
(All of these apply to public transport journeys; the wait for the vehicle does not generally apply to car or
bicycle
A bicycle, also called a pedal cycle, bike, push-bike or cycle, is a human-powered transport, human-powered or motorized bicycle, motor-assisted, bicycle pedal, pedal-driven, single-track vehicle, with two bicycle wheel, wheels attached to a ...
journeys, and for walk-only journeys, there is no division into parts.)
Typically, although travellers "dislike" all time spent travelling, they dislike walking and waiting parts of the journey more than in-vehicle journey time, and thus would be willing to pay more to avoid them. This results in a higher value of time for those parts of the journey than the main in-vehicle part of the journey. The function ''u(w)'' mentioned earlier can therefore be considered to consist of differing sets of valued time.
An alternative approach to applying different values of time to each part of the journey is to apply a weighting to time spent on each different part of the journey which quantifies the level of dislike a traveller has for time spent on that bit of the journey relative to time spent in-vehicle. For example, if a traveller considers 10 minutes' walk to be "as bad" as 12 minutes in a vehicle, then each minute of walking time is equivalent to 1.2 minutes of in-vehicle time. In this manner, all parts of the journey can be converted into their equivalent in-vehicle time.
Once the equivalent in-vehicle time for the whole journey is calculated, this can be converted to a monetary value as described earlier.
Generalised time
If the monetary cost of the journey (''p'') is considered to be irrelevant for the purposes of the exercise (for example, when comparing different journey options through a public transport network when fares are constant), there is no need to convert the generalised cost to a currency value - instead, it can be left in units of time, as long as all time is equivalent (for example, if all time is converted to in-vehicle time). These units of time may be referred to as generalised time.
References
{{DEFAULTSORT:Generalised Cost
Transport economics
Freight transport