
Doux commerce (lit. ''gentle commerce'' or ''soft commerce'') is a concept originating from the
Age of Enlightenment stating that
commerce tends to civilize people, making them less likely to resort to violent or irrational behaviors.
This theory has also been referred to as commercial republicanism.
Origin and meaning
Proponents of the doux commerce theory argued that the spread of trade and commerce will decrease violence, including open warfare.
Montesquieu wrote, for example, that "wherever the ways of man are gentle, there is commerce; and wherever there is commerce, there the ways of men are gentle"
and "The natural effect of commerce is to lead to peace".
Thomas Paine argued that "If commerce were permitted to act to the universal extent it is capable, it would extirpate the system of war".
Engaging in trade has been described as "civilizing" people, which has been related to virtues such as being "reasonable and prudent; less given to political and, especially, religious enthusiasm; more reliable, honest, thrifty, and industrious".
In the greater scheme of things, trade was seen as responsible for ensuring stability, tolerance, reciprocity and fairness.
It is not clear when this term was coined. Writings of
Jacques Savary, a 17th-century French merchant, have been suggested as one possible origin
but similar use has been traced earlier, for example to a
Renaissance-era 16th century work by
Michel de Montaigne
Michel Eyquem, Sieur de Montaigne ( ; ; 28 February 1533 – 13 September 1592), also known as the Lord of Montaigne, was one of the most significant philosophers of the French Renaissance. He is known for popularizing the essay as a liter ...
.
The basic idea that trade lessens the chance for conflict between nations can be traced as far as writings of
Ancient Greece.
It became popular in the 17th century writings of some scholars from the Age of Enlightenment, and has been endorsed by thinkers like Montesquieu,
Voltaire,
Smith, and
Hume
Hume most commonly refers to:
* David Hume (1711–1776), Scottish philosopher
Hume may also refer to:
People
* Hume (surname)
* Hume (given name)
* James Hume Nisbet (1849–1923), Scottish-born novelist and artist
In fiction
* Hume, the ...
, as well as
Immanuel Kant.
It has been discussed in their essays and literary works; for example Voltaire's poem ''
Le Mondain
"Le Mondain" ("The Worldling" or "The Man of the World") is a philosophical poem written by French enlightenment writer and philosopher Voltaire in 1736. It satirises Christian imagery, including the story of Adam and Eve, to defend a way of li ...
'' (1736) has been described as endorsing the doux commerce theory.
Out of those, Montesquieu has been argued to be the writer most responsible for the spread of this idea in his influential ''
Spirit of Law'' (1748),
and the theory is sometimes described as "Montesquieu's doux commerce." (although Montesquieu did not use the term itself).
In modern scholarship, the term has been analyzed by economist
Albert Hirschman
Albert may refer to:
Companies
* Albert (supermarket), a supermarket chain in the Czech Republic
* Albert Heijn, a supermarket chain in the Netherlands
* Albert Market, a street market in The Gambia
* Albert Productions, a record label
* Albe ...
in his 1977 work ''
The Passions and the Interests: Political Arguments For Capitalism Before Its Triumph.'' Hirschman is credited with summarizing the doux commerce argument for the modern readers and popularizing the term in modern discourse.
Critique
At the same time, even Montesquieu and other proponents of trade from the Enlightenment era have cautioned that some social effects of commerce may be negative, for example
commodification
Within a capitalist economic system, commodification is the transformation of things such as goods, services, ideas, nature, personal information, people or animals into objects of trade or commodities.For animals"United Nations Commodity Trad ...
,
conspicuous consumption
In sociology and in economics, the term conspicuous consumption describes and explains the consumer practice of buying and using goods of a higher quality, price, or in greater quantity than practical. In 1899, the sociologist Thorstein Veblen co ...
, or erosion of interest in non-commercial affairs.
Edmund Burke
Edmund Burke (; 12 January NS.html"_;"title="New_Style.html"_;"title="/nowiki>New_Style">NS">New_Style.html"_;"title="/nowiki>New_Style">NS/nowiki>_1729_–_9_July_1797)_was_an_ NS.html"_;"title="New_Style.html"_;"title="/nowiki>New_Style"> ...
offered the following critique of the doux commerce idea: that it is not commerce that civilizes humans, it is that humans are civilized through culture, which enables them to engage in commerce.
This theory led to trade becoming associated with peaceful and inoffensive activities representative of the "civilized" West European nations; which has however been criticized by later scholars as omitting the facts that much of the said "gentle" trade and resulting prosperity was built on activities like the
slave trade and
colonial exploitation.
This follows the criticism of Marx. He gives the examples of the slave trade in the Netherlands in the 17th century, and the genocide of a million Indians in 1866 due to famine, caused by the hoarding of rice by the English.
The doux commerce theory continues to be debated in the modern times. The question of whether commerce's impact on the society is net positive or net negative has no conclusive answer. Mark Movsesian noted that "as Hirschman once suggested, the doux commerce thesis is right and wrong at the same time: the market both promotes and corrupts good morals."
See also
*
Capitalist peace
*
Classic liberalism
*
Economic liberalism
*
Gains from trade
In economics, gains from trade are the net benefits to economic agents from being allowed an increase in voluntary trading with each other. In technical terms, they are the increase of consumer surplus plus producer surplus from lower tariffs ...
*
Mercantilism
Mercantilism is an economic policy that is designed to maximize the exports and minimize the imports for an economy. It promotes imperialism, colonialism, tariffs and subsidies on traded goods to achieve that goal. The policy aims to reduce a ...
*
Moral progress
*
Peace economics
*
Wandel durch Handel
References
{{Reflist
Early Modern economics
History of international trade
Enlightenment philosophy
Peace
Montesquieu