HOME

TheInfoList



OR:

In
discrete mathematics Discrete mathematics is the study of mathematical structures that can be considered "discrete" (in a way analogous to discrete variables, having a bijection with the set of natural numbers) rather than "continuous" (analogously to continu ...
, a discrete fixed-point is a
fixed-point Fixed point may refer to: * Fixed point (mathematics), a value that does not change under a given transformation * Fixed-point arithmetic, a manner of doing arithmetic on computers * Fixed point, a benchmark (surveying) The term benchmark, be ...
for functions defined on finite sets, typically subsets of the integer grid \mathbb^n. Discrete fixed-point theorems were developed by Iimura, Murota and Tamura, Chen and Deng and others. Yang provides a survey.


Basic concepts

Continuous fixed-point theorems often require a continuous function. Since continuity is not meaningful for functions on discrete sets, it is replaced by conditions such as a
direction-preserving function In discrete mathematics, a direction-preserving function (or mapping) is a function on a discrete space, such as the integer grid, that (informally) does not change too drastically between two adjacent points. It can be considered a discrete analogu ...
. Such conditions imply that the function does not change too drastically when moving between neighboring points of the integer grid. There are various direction-preservation conditions, depending on whether neighboring points are considered points of a hypercube (HGDP), of a simplex (SGDP) etc. See the page on
direction-preserving function In discrete mathematics, a direction-preserving function (or mapping) is a function on a discrete space, such as the integer grid, that (informally) does not change too drastically between two adjacent points. It can be considered a discrete analogu ...
for definitions. Continuous fixed-point theorems often require a
convex set In geometry, a subset of a Euclidean space, or more generally an affine space over the reals, is convex if, given any two points in the subset, the subset contains the whole line segment that joins them. Equivalently, a convex set or a convex ...
. The analogue of this property for discrete sets is an
integrally-convex set An integrally convex set is the discrete geometry analogue of the concept of convex set in geometry. A subset ''X'' of the integer grid \mathbb^n is integrally convex if any point ''y'' in the convex hull of ''X'' can be expressed as a convex comb ...
. A fixed point of a discrete function ''f'' is defined exactly as for continuous functions: it is a point ''x'' for which ''f''(''x'')=''x''.


For functions on discrete sets

We focus on functions f: X\to \mathbb^n, where the domain X is a nonempty subset of the Euclidean space \mathbb^n. ch(''X'') denotes the convex hull of ''X''. Iimura-Murota-Tamura theorem: If ''X'' is a finite integrally-convex subset of \mathbb^n, and f: X\to \text(X) is a ''hypercubic direction-preserving (HDP)'' function, then ''f'' has a fixed-point. Chen-Deng theorem: If ''X'' is a finite subset of \mathbb^n, and f: X\to \text(X) is ''simplicially direction-preserving'' ''(SDP)'', then ''f'' has a fixed-point. Yang's theorems: * .6 If ''X'' is a finite integrally-convex subset of \mathbb^n, f: X\to \mathbb^n is ''simplicially gross direction preserving (SGDP)'', and for all ''x'' in ''X'' there exists some ''g''(''x'')>0 such that x+g(x)f(x)\in \text(X), then ''f'' has a zero point. * .7 If ''X'' is a finite hypercubic subset of \mathbb^n, with minimum point ''a'' and maximum point ''b'', f: X\to \mathbb^n is SGDP, and for any ''x'' in ''X'': f_i(x_1,\ldots,x_,a_i,x_,\ldots,x_n) \leq 0 and f_i(x_1,\ldots,x_,b_i,x_,\ldots,x_n) \geq 0, then ''f'' has a zero point. This is a discrete analogue of the
Poincaré–Miranda theorem In mathematics, the Poincaré–Miranda theorem is a generalization of intermediate value theorem, from a single function in a single dimension, to functions in dimensions. It says as follows: ::Consider n continuous functions of n variables, f_ ...
. It is a consequence of the previous theorem. * .8 If ''X'' is a finite integrally-convex subset of \mathbb^n, and f: X\to \text(X) is such that f(x)-x is ''SGDP'', then ''f'' has a fixed-point. This is a discrete analogue of the
Brouwer fixed-point theorem Brouwer's fixed-point theorem is a fixed-point theorem in topology, named after L. E. J. (Bertus) Brouwer. It states that for any continuous function f mapping a compact convex set to itself there is a point x_0 such that f(x_0)=x_0. The simpl ...
. * .9 If X = \mathbb^n, f: X\to \mathbb^n is bounded and f(x)-x is SGDP, then ''f'' has a fixed-point (this follows easily from the previous theorem by taking ''X'' to be a subset of \mathbb^n that bounds ''f''). *
.10 Tenth may refer to: Numbers * 10th, the ordinal form of the number ten * One tenth, , or 0.1, a fraction, one part of a unit divided equally into ten parts. ** the SI prefix deci- ** tithe, a one-tenth part of something * 1/10 of any unit of ...
If ''X'' is a finite integrally-convex subset of \mathbb^n, F: X\to 2^X a point-to-set mapping, and for all ''x'' in ''X'': F(x) = \text(F(x))\cap \mathbb^n , and there is a function ''f'' such that f(x)\in \text(F(x)) and f(x)-x is SGDP, then there is a point ''y'' in ''X'' such that y \in F(y). This is a discrete analogue of the
Kakutani fixed-point theorem In mathematical analysis, the Kakutani fixed-point theorem is a fixed-point theorem for set-valued functions. It provides sufficient conditions for a set-valued function defined on a convex, compact subset of a Euclidean space to have a fixed poin ...
, and the function ''f'' is an analogue of a continuous selection function. *
.12 Tenth may refer to: Numbers * 10th, the ordinal form of the number ten * One tenth, , or 0.1, a fraction, one part of a unit divided equally into ten parts. ** the SI prefix deci- ** tithe, a one-tenth part of something * 1/10 of any unit of me ...
Suppose ''X'' is a finite integrally-convex subset of \mathbb^n, and it is also ''symmetric'' in the sense that ''x'' is in ''X'' iff -''x'' is in ''X''. If f: X\to \mathbb^n is SGDP w.r.t. a ''weakly-symmetric'' triangulation of ch(''X'') (in the sense that if ''s'' is a simplex on the boundary of the triangulation iff -''s'' is), and f(x)\cdot f(-y) \leq 0 for every pair of simplicially-connected points ''x'', ''y'' in the boundary of ch(''X''), then ''f'' has a zero point. *See the survey for more theorems. *


For discontinuous functions on continuous sets

Discrete fixed-point theorems are closely related to fixed-point theorems on discontinuous functions. These, too, use the direction-preservation condition instead of continuity. Herings-Laan-Talman-Yang fixed-point theorem: Let ''X'' be a non-empty convex compact subset of \mathbb^n. Let ''f'': ''X'' → ''X'' be a ''locally gross direction preserving (LGDP)'' function: at any point ''x'' that is not a fixed point of ''f'', the direction of f(x)-x is grossly preserved in some neighborhood of ''x'', in the sense that for any two points ''y'', ''z'' in this neighborhood, its inner product is non-negative, i.e.: (f(y)-y)\cdot (f(z)-z) \geq 0. Then ''f'' has a fixed point in ''X''. The theorem is originally stated for polytopes, but Philippe Bich extends it to convex compact sets.Note that every continuous function is LGDP, but an LGDP function may be discontinuous. An LGDP function may even be neither upper nor lower
semi-continuous In mathematical analysis, semicontinuity (or semi-continuity) is a property of extended real-valued functions that is weaker than continuity. An extended real-valued function f is upper (respectively, lower) semicontinuous at a point x_0 if, r ...
. Moreover, there is a constructive algorithm for approximating this fixed point.


Applications

Discrete fixed-point theorems have been used to prove the existence of a
Nash equilibrium In game theory, the Nash equilibrium, named after the mathematician John Nash, is the most common way to define the solution of a non-cooperative game involving two or more players. In a Nash equilibrium, each player is assumed to know the equ ...
in a discrete game, and the existence of a
Walrasian equilibrium Competitive equilibrium (also called: Walrasian equilibrium) is a concept of economic equilibrium introduced by Kenneth Arrow and Gérard Debreu in 1951 appropriate for the analysis of commodity markets with flexible prices and many traders, and s ...
in a discrete market.


References

{{reflist Discrete mathematics Fixed-point theorems