HOME

TheInfoList



OR:

Congestion games (CG) are a class of games in
game theory Game theory is the study of mathematical models of strategic interactions. It has applications in many fields of social science, and is used extensively in economics, logic, systems science and computer science. Initially, game theory addressed ...
. They represent situations which commonly occur in roads,
communication networks A telecommunications network is a group of nodes interconnected by telecommunications links that are used to exchange messages between the nodes. The links may use a variety of technologies based on the methodologies of circuit switching, messag ...
,
oligopoly An oligopoly () is a market in which pricing control lies in the hands of a few sellers. As a result of their significant market power, firms in oligopolistic markets can influence prices through manipulating the supply function. Firms in ...
markets and natural habitats. There is a set of resources (e.g. roads or communication links); there are several players who need resources (e.g. drivers or network users); each player chooses a subset of these resources (e.g. a path in the network); the delay in each resource is determined by the number of players choosing a subset that contains this resource. The cost of each player is the sum of delays among all resources he chooses. Naturally, each player wants to minimize his own delay; however, each player's choices impose a negative
externality In economics, an externality is an Indirect costs, indirect cost (external cost) or indirect benefit (external benefit) to an uninvolved third party that arises as an effect of another party's (or parties') activity. Externalities can be conside ...
on the other players, which may lead to inefficient outcomes. The research of congestion games was initiated by the American economist
Robert W. Rosenthal Robert W. Rosenthal (1945 – February 7, 2002) was an American economist, most known for his contributions to game theory. He obtained a B.A. in political economy from Johns Hopkins University (1966), M.S. (1968) and Ph.D. (1971) in oper ...
in 1973.. He proved that every congestion game has a Nash equilibrium in
pure strategies In game theory, a move, action, or play is any one of the options which a player can choose in a setting where the optimal outcome depends ''not only'' on their own actions ''but'' on the actions of others. The discipline mainly concerns the actio ...
(aka ''pure Nash equilibrium'', PNE). During the proof, he in fact proved that every congestion game is an exact potential game. Later, Monderer and Shapley proved a converse result: any game with an exact potential function is equivalent to some congestion game. Later research focused on questions such as: * Does the existence of equilibrium, as well as the existence of a potential function, extend to more general models of congestion games? * What is the quantitative inefficiency of congestion games? * What is the
computational complexity In computer science, the computational complexity or simply complexity of an algorithm is the amount of resources required to run it. Particular focus is given to computation time (generally measured by the number of needed elementary operations ...
of finding an equilibrium?


Example

Consider a traffic net where two players originate at point and need to get to point . Suppose that node is connected to node via two paths: and , where is a little closer than (i.e. is more likely to be chosen by each player), as in the picture at the right. The roads from both connection points to get easily congested, meaning the more players pass through a point, the greater the delay of each player becomes, so having both players go through the same connection point causes extra delay. Formally, the delay in each of and when players go there is x^2. A good outcome in this game will be for the two players to "coordinate" and pass through different connection points. Can such an outcome be achieved? The following matrix expresses the costs of the players in terms of delays depending on their choices: The pure
Nash equilibria In game theory, the Nash equilibrium is the most commonly used solution concept for non-cooperative games. A Nash equilibrium is a situation where no player could gain by changing their own strategy (holding all other players' strategies fixed) ...
in this game are (OAT,OBT) and (OBT,OAT): any unilateral change by one of the players increases the cost of this player (note that the values in the table are costs, so players prefer them to be smaller). In this example, the Nash equilibrium is ''efficient'' - the players choose different lanes and the sum of costs is minimal. In contrast, suppose the delay in each of and when players go there is 0.8 x. Then the cost matrix is: Now, the only pure Nash equilibrium is : any player switching to OBT increases his cost from 2.6 to 2.8. An equilibrium still exists, but it is not efficient: the sum of costs is 5.2, while the sum of cost in and is 4.6.


Basic result


Notation

The basic definition of a CG has the following components. * A base set of congestible elements (also called ''resources'' or ''factors''). In the above example, is the set of roads (, , and ). * A set of players. In the above example n=2. * A finite set of strategies S_i for each player, where each strategy P \in S_i is a subset of . ** In the above example, both players have the same set of strategies: S_1 = S_2 = \. CGs in which all players have the same set of strategies are called symmetric CGs. In general, different players may have different sets, for example, if each player has a different source and/or a different target. Such CGs are called asymmetric CGs. ** In general, a strategy can be any subset of . CGs in which a strategy can only be a path in a given graph (as in the above example) are called network CGs. CGs in which a strategy can only be a single resource are called singleton CGs. * For each element e\in E and a vector of strategies (P_1, P_2, \ldots, P_n), the ''load'' is defined as x_e = \#\. * For each element e\in E there is a delay function d_e : \mathbb \longrightarrow \mathbb (also called latency function or cost function). Given a vector of strategies, the delay on is d_e(x_e). Each d_e is assumed to be positive and
monotone increasing In mathematics, a monotonic function (or monotone function) is a function between ordered sets that preserves or reverses the given order. This concept first arose in calculus, and was later generalized to the more abstract setting of ord ...
. * Given a strategy P_i, player experiences delay \textstyle \sum_ d_e(x_e); each player wants to minimize his delay. * A ''Nash equilibrium'' is a vector of strategies (P_1, P_2, \ldots, P_n) such that, for each player , replacing P_i with a different strategy Q_i would not decrease the delay experienced by .


Existence of Nash equilibria

Every CG has a
Nash equilibrium In game theory, the Nash equilibrium is the most commonly used solution concept for non-cooperative games. A Nash equilibrium is a situation where no player could gain by changing their own strategy (holding all other players' strategies fixed) ...
in
pure strategies In game theory, a move, action, or play is any one of the options which a player can choose in a setting where the optimal outcome depends ''not only'' on their own actions ''but'' on the actions of others. The discipline mainly concerns the actio ...
. This can be shown by constructing a ''potential function'' that assigns a value to each outcome. Moreover, this construction will also show that iterated
best response In game theory, the best response is the strategy (or strategies) which produces the most favorable outcome for a player, taking other players' strategies as given. The concept of a best response is central to John Nash's best-known contribution ...
finds a Nash equilibrium. Define \textstyle\Phi = \sum_ \sum_^ d_e(k). Note that this function is ''not'' the social welfare \textstyle\sum_ x_e d_e(x_e), but rather a discrete integral of sorts. The critical property of a potential function for a congestion game is that if one player switches strategy, the change in his delay is equal to the change in the potential function. Consider the case when player switches from P_i to Q_i. Elements that are in both of the strategies remain unaffected, elements that the player leaves (i.e. e \in P_i - Q_i) decrease the potential by d_e (x_e), and the elements the player joins (i.e. e \in Q_i - P_i) increase the potential by d_e(x_e+1). This change in potential is precisely the change in delay for player , so \Phi is in fact a potential function. Now observe that any minimum of \Phi is a pure Nash equilibrium. Fixing all but one player, any improvement in strategy by that player corresponds to decreasing \Phi, which cannot happen at a minimum. Now since there are a finite number of configurations and each d_e is monotone, there exists an equilibrium. The existence of a potential function has an additional implication, called the finite improvement property (FIP). If we start with any strategy-vector, pick a player arbitrarily, and let him change his strategy to a better strategy for him, and repeat, then the sequence of improvements must be finite (that is, the sequence will not cycle). This is because each such improvement strictly increases the potential.


Extensions

Below we present various extensions and variations on the basic CG model.


Nonatomic congestion games

A nonatomic (aka continuous) CG is the limit of a standard CG with ''n'' players, as n \rightarrow \infty. There is a continuum of players, the players are considered "infinitesimally small", and each individual player has a negligible effect on the congestion. Nonatomic CGs were studied by Milchtaich, Friedman and Blonsky. * We keep a ''finite'' set of congestible elements. * Instead of recognizing players, as in the discrete case, we have ''types'' of players, where each type is associated with a number r_i, representing the ''rate'' of traffic for that type. * Each agent in type ''i'' picks a strategy from the strategy set S_i. * As before, the delay functions d_e are monotone and positive, but we now add the assumption that they are
continuous Continuity or continuous may refer to: Mathematics * Continuity (mathematics), the opposing concept to discreteness; common examples include ** Continuous probability distribution or random variable in probability and statistics ** Continuous ...
as well. * We allow players in a type to distribute fractionally over their strategy set. That is, for every strategy P \in S_i, let f_P denote the fraction of players in type using strategy . By definition, \textstyle \sum_ f_P = r_i. * For each element e\in E, the ''load'' is defined as the sum of fractions of players using ''e'', that is, x_e = \sum_ f_P.


Existence of equilibria in nonatomic CGs

Strategies are now collections of strategy profiles f_P. For a strategy set S_i of size , the collection of all valid profiles is a
compact subset In mathematics, specifically general topology, compactness is a property that seeks to generalize the notion of a closed and bounded subset of Euclidean space. The idea is that a compact space has no "punctures" or "missing endpoints", i.e., it ...
of ,r_in. We now define the potential function as \textstyle \Phi = \sum_ \int_0^ d_e(z) \, dz, replacing the discrete integral with the standard one. As a function of the strategy, \Phi is continuous: d_e is continuous by assumption, and x_e is a continuous function of the strategy. Then by the
extreme value theorem In calculus, the extreme value theorem states that if a real-valued function f is continuous on the closed and bounded interval ,b/math>, then f must attain a maximum and a minimum, each at least once. That is, there exist numbers c and ...
, \Phi attains its global minimum. The final step is to show that a minimum of \Phi is indeed a Nash equilibrium. Assume for contradiction that there exists a collection of f_P that minimize \Phi but are not a Nash equilibrium. Then for some type , there exists some improvement Q\in S_i over the current choice . That is, \textstyle \sum_ d_e(x_e) < \sum_ d_e(x_e) . The idea now is to take a small amount \delta < f_P of players using strategy and move them to strategy . Now for any x_e \in Q, we have increased its load by \delta, so its term in \Phi is now \textstyle \int_0^ d_e(z)dz. Differentiating the integral, this change is approximately \delta \cdot d_e(x_e), with error \delta^2. The equivalent analysis of the change holds when we look at edges in . Therefore, the change in potential is approximately \textstyle \delta (\sum_ d_e(x_e) - \sum_ d_e(x_e)), which is less than zero. This is a contradiction, as then \Phi was not minimized. Therefore, a minimum of \Phi must be a Nash equilibrium.


Splittable congestion games

In a splittable CG, as in an atomic CG, there are finitely many players, each of whom has a certain load to transfer. As in nonatomic CGs, each player can split his load into fractional loads going through different paths, like a transportation company choosing a set of paths for mass transportation. In contrast to nonatomic CGs, each player has a non-negligible effect on the congestion. Splittable CGs were first analyzed by Ariel Orda,
Raphael Rom Raphael "Raphi" Rom () is an Israeli computer scientist working at Technion – Israel Institute of Technology. Rom earned his Ph.D. in 1975 from the University of Utah, under the supervision of Thomas Stockham. He is known for his contribution ...
and Nachum Shimkin in 1993, in the context of communication networks. They show that, for a simple network with two nodes and multiple parallel links, the Nash equilibrium is unique under reasonable convexity conditions, and has some interesting monotonicity properties. For general network topologies, more complex conditions are required to guarantee the uniqueness of Nash equilibrium.


Weighted congestion games

In a weighted CG, different players may have different effects on the congestion. For example, in a road network, a
truck A truck or lorry is a motor vehicle designed to transport freight, carry specialized payloads, or perform other utilitarian work. Trucks vary greatly in size, power, and configuration, but the vast majority feature body-on-frame construct ...
adds congestion much more than a
motorcycle A motorcycle (motorbike, bike; uni (if one-wheeled); trike (if three-wheeled); quad (if four-wheeled)) is a lightweight private 1-to-2 passenger personal motor vehicle Steering, steered by a Motorcycle handlebar, handlebar from a saddle-style ...
. In general, the weight of a player may depend on the resource (resource-specific weights): for every player ''i'' and resource ''e'', there is weight w_, and the load on the resource ''e'' is x_e = \sum_ w_. An important special case is when the weight depends only on the player (resource-independent weights), that is, each player i has a weight w_i, and x_e = \sum_ w_.


Weighted singleton CGs with resource-independent weights

Milchtaich considered the special case of weighted CGs in which each strategy is a single resource ("singleton CG"), the weights are ''resource-independent'', and all players have the same strategy set. The following is proved: * If all players have the same delay functions, then the game has the finite-improvement property (and thus has a PNE). * If there are only two strategies (and arbitrarily many players with possibly different delay functions), then the game has the finite-improvement property (and thus has a PNE). * If there are only two players (with possibly different delay functions), then the game has the finite-best-response property (and thus has a PNE). * If there are three or more strategies and three or more players with different delay functions, a PNE might not exist.


Weighted network CGs

Milchtaich considered the special case of weighted CGs in which each strategy is a path in a given undirected graph ("network CG"). He proved that every finite game can be represented as a weighted network congestion game, with nondecreasing (but not necessarily negative) cost-functions. This implies that not every such game has a PNE. Concrete examples of weighted CGs without PNE are given by Libman and Orda, as well as Goemans Mirrokni and Vetta. This raises the question of what conditions guarantee the existence of PNE. In particular, we say that a certain graph ''G guarantees'' a certain property if every weighted network CG in which the underlying network is ''G'' has that property. Milchtaich characterized networks that guarantee the existence of PNE, as well as the finite-improvement property, with the additional condition that a player with a lower weight has weakly more allowed strategies (formally, w_i < w_j implies , S_i, \geq , S_j, ). He proved that: * A graph ''G'' guarantees the finite-improvement property iff ''G'' is homeomorphic to either a ''parallel network'' (a graph made of one or more single-edge networks connected in parallel), or to a parallel network connected in series with one or two single-edge networks. * A graph ''G'' guarantees the existence of a PNE iff ''G'' is homeomorphic to a connection in series of one or more networks from a set of six "allowed networks"; an equivalent condition is that no network from a set of six "forbidden network" is embedded in ''G''. In the special case in which every player is allowed to use any strategy ("public edges"), there are more networks that guarantee the existence of PNE; a complete characterization of such networks is posed as an open problem. Mlichtaich analyzes the effect of network topology on the ''efficiency'' of PNE: * A graph ''G'' guarantees that every PNE is Pareto-efficient, iff three simple "forbidden networks" are not embedded in ''G''. * A graph ''G'' guarantees that
Braess's paradox Braess's paradox is the observation that adding one or more roads to a road network can slow down overall road traffic, traffic flow through it. The paradox was first discovered by Arthur Cecil Pigou, Arthur Pigou in 1920, and Stigler's law of ep ...
does not occur, iff it is a series-parallel graph. Milchtaich analyzes the effect of network topology on the ''uniqueness'' of the PNE costs: * A graph ''G'' guarantees that the PNE costs are unique iff ''G'' is a connection in series of one or more networks of several simple kinds. * A graph ''G'' does ''not'' guarantee that PNE costs are unique iff ''G'' contains an embedded network of a particular simple type. Holzman and Law-Yone also characterize the networks that guarantee that every atomic CG has a strong PNE, a unique PNE, or a
Pareto-efficient In welfare economics, a Pareto improvement formalizes the idea of an outcome being "better in every possible way". A change is called a Pareto improvement if it leaves at least one person in society better off without leaving anyone else worse ...
PNE. Richman and Shimkin characterize the networks that guarantee that every ''splittable'' CG has a unique PNE.


General weighted CGs

We say that a class ''C'' of functions ''guarantees'' a certain property if every weighted CG in which all delay functions are elements of ''C'' has that property. * Fotakis, Kontogiannis and Spirakis prove that the class of linear functions guarantees the existence of an exact potential, and hence the existence of PNE. * Panagopoulou and Spirakis prove that the class of exponential functions guarantees the existence of a weighted potential, and hence the existence of PNE. * Harks, Klimm and Mohring prove that a class of functions guarantees the existence of an exact potential, if and only if it contains only affine functions. This characterization remain valid when restricted to two-player games, three-resource games, singleton games, games with symmetric strategies, or games with integral weights. Moreover, a class of functions guarantees the existence of a weighted potential, if and only if either (1) it contains only affine functions, or (2) it contains only exponential functions of the form a_e \cdot \exp + b_e, where \phi is the same for all resources. This characterization remain valid when restricted to four-player games, four-resource games, singleton games, games with symmetric strategies, or games with integral weights. For two-player games, a class of functions guarantees the existence of a weighted potential, if and only if all functions in it are of the form a_e \cdot f(x_e) + b_e, where is a monotone function (the same for all resources). * Harks and Klimm prove a similar result for the existence of PNE: they prove that a class of functions guarantees the existence of PNE if and only if either (1) it contains only affine functions, or (2) it contains only exponential functions of the form a_e \cdot \exp + b_e, where \phi is the same for all resources. This characterization remain valid when restricted to three-player games. For two-player games, a class of functions guarantees the existence of PNE if and only if all functions in it are of the form a_e \cdot f(x_e) + b_e, where is a monotone function (the same for all resources).


Other results

There are many other papers about weighted congestion games.


Player-specific cost functions

The basic CG model can be extended by allowing the delay function of each resource to depend on the player. So for each resource ''e'' and player ''i'', there is a delay function d_. Given a strategy P_i, player experiences delay \textstyle \sum_ d_(x_e).


Player-specific costs in singleton CGs (crowding games)

Milchtaich introduced and studied CGs with player-specific costs in the following special case: * Each player chooses a single resource (such games are called singleton CGs); * All players have the same set of strategies. This special case of CG is also called a crowding game. It represents a setting in which several people simultaneously choose a place to go to (e.g. a room, a settlement, a restaurant), and their payoff is determined both by the place and by the number of other players choosing the same place. In a crowding game, given a strategy P_i=\, player experiences delay d_(x_). If the player switches to a different strategy , his delay would be d_(x_f+1); hence, a strategy vector is a PNE iff for every player i, d_(x_)\leq d_(x_+1) for all ''e'',''f''. In general, CGs with player-specific delays might ''not'' admit a
potential Potential generally refers to a currently unrealized ability. The term is used in a wide variety of fields, from physics to the social sciences to indicate things that are in a state where they are able to change in ways ranging from the simple r ...
function. For example, suppose there are three resources x,y,z and two players A and B with the following delay functions: * d_(1) < d_(0) < d_(2) < d_(0) < d_(2) < d_(2) * d_(1) < d_(0) < d_(2) < d_(0) < d_(2) < d_(2) The following is a cyclic improvement path: (z,y) \to (y,y) \to (y,z) \to (x,z)\to (x,x)\to (z,x) \to (z,y) . This shows that the finite-improvement property does not hold, so the game cannot have a potential function (not even a generalized-ordinal-potential function). However: * With only two resources, the finite improvement property holds. Hence, a PNE exists. * With only two players, every finite best-response property holds. Hence, a PNE exists. When there are three or more players, even best-response paths might be cyclic. However, every CG still has a PNE. The proof is constructive and shows an algorithm that finds a Nash equilibrium in at most steps. Moreover, every CG is weakly acyclic: for any initial strategy-vector, at least one best-response path starting at this vector has a length of at most r , which terminates at an equilibrium. Every crowding game is ''sequentially solvable''. This means that, for every ordering of the players, the
sequential game In game theory, a sequential game is defined as a game where one player selects their action before others, and subsequent players are informed of that choice before making their own decisions. This turn-based structure, governed by a time axis, d ...
in which each player in turn picks a strategy has a subgame-perfect equilibrium in which the players' actions are a PNE in the original simultaneous game. Every crowding game has at least one strong PNE; every strong PNE of a crowding game can be attained as a subgame-perfect equilibrium of a sequential version of the game. In general, a crowding game might have many different PNE. For example, suppose there are ''n'' players and ''n'' resources, and the negative effect of congestion on the payoff is much higher than the positive value of the resources. Then there are n! different PNEs: every one-to-one matching of players to resources is a PNE, as no player would move to a resource occupied by another player. However, if a crowding game is replicated ''m'' times, then the set of PNEs converges to a single point as ''m'' goes to infinity. Moreover, in a "large" (nonatomic) crowding game, there is generically a unique PNE. This PNE has an interesting graph-theoretic property. Let ''G'' be a
bipartite graph In the mathematics, mathematical field of graph theory, a bipartite graph (or bigraph) is a Graph (discrete mathematics), graph whose vertex (graph theory), vertices can be divided into two disjoint sets, disjoint and Independent set (graph theo ...
with players on one side and resources on the other side, where each player is adjacent to all the resources that his copies choose in the unique PNE. Then G contains no cycles.


Separable cost functions

A special case of the player-specific delay functions is that the delay functions can be separated into a player-specific factor and a general factor. There are two sub-cases: * Multiplicatively-separable cost functions: d_(x_) = a_\cdot d(x_e), where a_ is a constant that represents the base cost of resource ''e'' to player ''i'', and ''d'' is a general delay function (the same for all resources). * Additively-separable cost functions: d_(x_) = a_ + d(x_e), where a_ is a constant that represents the fixed cost of resource ''e'' to player ''i,'' and ''d'' is a general delay function (the same for all resources). When only pure-strategies are considered, these two notions are equivalent, since the logarithm of a product is a sum. Moreover, when players may have resource-specific weights, the setting with resource-specific delay functions can be reduced to the setting with a universal delay function. Games with separable cost functions occur in load-balancing, M/M/1 queueing, and habitat selection. The following is known about weighted singleton CGs with separable costs: * If the base costs a_ are player-independent (a_ = a_e for every player ''i''), then the CG has the FIP, hence it has a PNE. The same holds if the base costs are resource-independent (a_ = a_i for every resource ''e''). The proof is based on a vector-valued potential function. For each state of the game, the potential is a vector of size ''n'' containing the costs of all players, sorted from large to small. Whenever a player deviates to a resource with a smaller cost for him, the vector of costs becomes smaller in the leximin order. *If the weights are player-independent (equivalently: the CG is unweighted and the delay-functions are resource-specific), then it has the FIP, hence it has a PNE. If the cost-functions are additively-separable, then the game even has an exact potential function. The result holds even if the cost functions are not monotonically-increasing with the load. If the cost-functions are not additively-separable, then FIP may not hold, and there may be no potential function, but a PNE still exists. *If the weights are resource-independent, then a PNE exists in the following cases: **When there are at most ''three'' players, a PNE exists, though the best-response improvement property might not hold. In contrast, there is a CG with separable costs and resource-independent weights with ''eight'' players in which no PNE exists. **When cost functions are additively-separable with linear variable-cost functions, the CG has a weighted potential, hence it has the FIP, hence it has a PNE. **When cost functions are additively-separable with logarithmic variable-cost function, and there are at most three players, the CG has the best-response improvement property, hence it has a PNE. However, it might not have the finite-improvement property. For more than three players, the existence of PNE is open. Every weighted ''singleton'' CG with separable player-specific preferences is isomorphic to a weighted ''network'' CG with player-independent preference.


Network CGs with player-specific costs

Milchtaich considered the special case of CGs with player-specific costs, in which each strategy is a path in a given graph ("network CG"). He proved that every finite game can be represented as an (unweighted) network congestion game with player-specific costs, with nondecreasing (but not necessarily negative) cost-functions. A complete characterization of networks that guarantee the existence of PNE in such CGs is posed as an open problem.


Computing a pure Nash equilibrium


Computing an equilibrium in unweighted CGs

The proof of existence of PNE is constructive: it shows a finite algorithm (an improvement path) that always finds a PNE. This raises the question of how many steps are required to find this PNE? Fabrikant, Papadimitriou and Talwar proved: * If all strategies are paths in a network ("network CG"), and all players have the same set of strategies ("symmetric CG"), then a PNE can be computed in polynomial time by maximizing the potential, through reduction to min-cost flow. The algorithm can be adapted to nonatomic CGs: under certain smoothness assumptions, a Nash equilibrium in such a game can be approximated in strongly-polynomial time. * If the strategies can be general subsets, or the players may have different sets of strategies ("asymmetric CG"), then computing a PNE is PLS-complete. This implies that there are examples with exponentially-long improvement paths. It also implies that finding a Nash equilibrium reachable from a specified state is
PSPACE-complete In computational complexity theory, a decision problem is PSPACE-complete if it can be solved using an amount of memory that is polynomial in the input length (PSPACE, polynomial space) and if every other problem that can be solved in polynomial sp ...
. * Every problem in the class PLS can be presented as a game whose pure equilibria are guaranteed to exist by a potential-function argument. Even-Dar, Kesselman and Mansour analyze the number of steps required for convergence to equilibrium in a load-balancing setting. Caragiannis, Fanelli, Gravin and Skopalik present an algorithm that computes a constant-factor approximation PNE. In particular: * With linear delay functions, the approximation ratio is 2+ε, and the runtime is polynomial in the number of players, the number of resources, and 1/ε. * When delay functions are degree-''d'' polynomials, the approximation ratio is ''d''O(''d'')''.'' Their algorithm identifies a short sequence of best-response moves, that leads to an approximate equilibrium. They also show that, for more general CGs, attaining any polynomial approximation of PNE is PLS-complete.


Computing an equilibrium in weighted network CGs

Fotakis, Kontogiannis and Spirakis present an algorithm that, in any weighted network CG with linear delay functions, finds a PNE in
pseudo-polynomial time In computational complexity theory, a numeric algorithm runs in pseudo-polynomial time if its running time is a polynomial in the ''numeric value'' of the input (the largest integer present in the input)—but not necessarily in the ''length'' of ...
(polynomial in the number of players ''n'' and the sum of players' weights ''W''). Their algorithm is a greedy best-response algorithm: players enter the game in descending order of their weight, and choose a best-response to existing players' strategies. Panagopoulou and Spirakis show empirical evidence that the algorithm of Fotakis, Kontogiannis and Spirakis in fact runs in time polynomial in ''n'' and log ''W''. They also propose an initial strategy-vector that dramatically speeds this algorithm. In general, a weighted network CG may not have a PNE. Milchtaich proves that deciding whether a given weighted network CG has a PNE is NP-hard even in the following cases: * There are two players; all players are allowed to use all paths; all cost-functions are nonnegative. * There are two players; the CG is unweighted; the costs are player-specific and nonnegative. The proof is by reduction from the directed edge-disjoint paths problem. Caragiannis, Fanelli, Gravin and Skopalik present an algorithm that computes a constant-factor approximation PNE in weighted CGs. In particular: *With linear delay functions, the approximation ratio is \frac+O(\epsilon), and the runtime is polynomial in the number of playres, the number of resources, and 1/ε. * When delay functions are degree-''d'' polynomials, the approximation ratio is d^''.'' To prove their results, they show that, although weighted CGs may not have a potential function, every weighted CG can be ''approximated'' by a certain potential game. This lets them show that every weighted CG has a (''d''!)-approximate PNE. Their algorithm identifies a short sequence of best-response moves, that leads to such an approximate PNE.


Summary of congestion game classifications

In summary, CGs can be classified according to various parameters: * Number and splittability of players: atomic CG, splittable CG or nonatomic CG; * Weight of players: unweighted CG or weighted CG (with resource-independent weights or resource-specific weights); * Cost functions for different players using the same resource: identical or player-specific (with separable or nonseparable cost-functions). * Possible strategies: one resource (singleton CG) or path in a network (network CG) or any subset (general CG). * Strategy sets of different players: different (asymmetric CG) or identical (symmetric CG).


See also

* Since every CG has a Nash equilibrium, the next natural topic is to analyze their quality. This is done using the concept of Price of anarchy in congestion games. * ּResource allocation games are somewhat related to congestion games. * Incomplete information: Facchini, van Megen, Borm and Tijs extend Rosenthal's model to a setting with
incomplete information In economics and game theory, complete information is an economic situation or game in which knowledge about other market participants or players is available to all participants. The utility functions (including risk aversion), payoffs, strategies ...
. They prove that the related Bayesian games are potential games, and therefore have pure Bayesian-Nash equilibria. * Coalitions: Fotakis, Kontogiannis and Spirakis study CGs in which players participate in coalitions. * Congestion games in nature: Milinsky describes an experiment in which a natural CG converges into a Nash equilibrium. In his experiment, he fed six sticklebacks from two ends of a tank. The fish distribution between the two ends was, on average, similar to the ratio of the food supply rates, so that no individual fish could increase his feeding rate by moving to the other side. Mlichtaich presents a more general treatment of CGs in
interspecific competition Interspecific competition, in ecology, is a form of competition in which individuals of ''different'' species compete for the same resources in an ecosystem (e.g. food or living space). This can be contrasted with mutualism, a type of symbiosis. ...
.


References


External links

* Lecture notes of Yishay Mansour abou
Potential and congestion games
* Lecture notes of Michal Feldman and Noam Nisan abou
Potential and congestion games
* {{Cite Algorithmic Game Theory 2007, pages = 28, 62, & 519 Game theory game classes