Concavification
   HOME

TheInfoList



OR:

In mathematics, concavification is the process of converting a non-concave function to a
concave function In mathematics, a concave function is one for which the function value at any convex combination of elements in the domain is greater than or equal to that convex combination of those domain elements. Equivalently, a concave function is any funct ...
. A related concept is convexification – converting a non-convex function to a
convex function In mathematics, a real-valued function is called convex if the line segment between any two distinct points on the graph of a function, graph of the function lies above or on the graph between the two points. Equivalently, a function is conve ...
. It is especially important in
economics Economics () is a behavioral science that studies the Production (economics), production, distribution (economics), distribution, and Consumption (economics), consumption of goods and services. Economics focuses on the behaviour and interac ...
and
mathematical optimization Mathematical optimization (alternatively spelled ''optimisation'') or mathematical programming is the selection of a best element, with regard to some criteria, from some set of available alternatives. It is generally divided into two subfiel ...
.


Concavification of a quasiconcave function by monotone transformation

An important special case of concavification is where the original function is a
quasiconcave function In mathematics, a quasiconvex function is a real-valued function defined on an interval or on a convex subset of a real vector space such that the inverse image of any set of the form (-\infty,a) is a convex set. For a function of a single ...
. It is known that: * Every concave function is quasiconcave, but the opposite is not true. * Every monotone transformation of a quasiconcave function is also quasiconcave. For example, if f : \mathbb^n \to \mathbb is quasiconcave and g : \mathbb \to \mathbb is a monotonically-increasing function, then x \mapsto g(f(x)) is also quasiconcave. Therefore, a natural question is: ''given a quasiconcave function'' f : \mathbb^n \to \mathbb, ''does there exist a monotonically increasing'' g : \mathbb \to \mathbb ''such that'' x \mapsto g(f(x)) ''is concave?''


Example and Counter Example

As an example, consider the function x \mapsto f(x) = x^2 on the domain x\geq 0. This function is quasiconcave, but it is not concave (in fact, it is strictly convex). It can be concavified, for example, using the monotone transformation t \mapsto g(t) = t^, since x \mapsto g(f(x))=\sqrt is concave. Not every concave function can be concavified in this way. A counter example was shown by Fenchel. His example is: (x,y) \mapsto f(x,y) := y + \sqrt. Fenchel proved that this function is quasiconcave, but there is no monotone transformation g : \mathbb\to\mathbb such that (x, y) \mapsto g(f(x,y)) is concave. Based on these examples, we define a function to be concavifiable if there exists a monotone transformation that makes it concave. The question now becomes: ''what quasiconcave functions are concavifiable?''


Concavifiability

Yakar Kannai treats the question in depth in the context of
utility function In economics, utility is a measure of a certain person's satisfaction from a certain state of the world. Over time, the term has been used with at least two meanings. * In a Normative economics, normative context, utility refers to a goal or ob ...
s, giving sufficient conditions under which continuous
convex preferences In economics, convex preferences are an individual's ordering of various outcomes, typically with regard to the amounts of various goods consumed, with the property that, roughly speaking, "averages are better than the extremes". This implies that ...
can be represented by concave utility functions. His results were later generalized by Connell and Rasmussen, who give necessary and sufficient conditions for concavifiability. They show that the function (x,y) \mapsto f(x,y) = e^\cdot y violates their conditions and thus is not concavifiable. They prove that this function is strictly quasiconcave and its gradient is non-vanishing, but it is not concavifiable.


References

{{Reflist Convex analysis