HOME

TheInfoList



OR:

In economics and econometrics, the Cobb–Douglas production function is a particular functional form of the production function, widely used to represent the technological relationship between the amounts of two or more inputs (particularly physical capital and labor) and the amount of output that can be produced by those inputs. The Cobb–Douglas form was developed and tested against statistical evidence by Charles Cobb and Paul Douglas between 1927 and 1947; according to Douglas, the functional form itself was developed earlier by Philip Wicksteed.


Formulation

In its most standard form for production of a single good with two factors, the function is : Y=AL^\beta K^\alpha where: * ''Y'' = total production (the real value of all goods produced in a year or 365.25 days) * ''L'' = labour input (person-hours worked in a year or 365.25 days) * ''K'' =
capital Capital may refer to: Common uses * Capital city, a municipality of primary status ** List of national capital cities * Capital letter, an upper-case letter Economics and social sciences * Capital (economics), the durable produced goods used f ...
input (a measure of all machinery, equipment, and buildings; the value of capital input divided by the price of capital) * ''A'' = total factor productivity * and are the output elasticities of capital and labor, respectively. These values are constants determined by available technology. Output elasticity measures the responsiveness of output to a change in levels of either labor or capital used in production,
ceteris paribus ' (also spelled '; () is a Latin phrase, meaning "other things equal"; some other English translations of the phrase are "all other things being equal", "other things held constant", "all else unchanged", and "all else being equal". A statement ...
. For example, if , a increase in capital usage would lead to approximately a increase in output. Sometimes the term has a more restricted meaning, requiring that the function display constant returns to scale, meaning that doubling the usage of capital ''K'' and labor ''L'' will also double output ''Y''. This holds if :, If :, returns to scale are decreasing, means that a percentage increase in capital ''K'' and labor ''L'' will produce a smaller percentage increase in output ''Y'', and if :, returns to scale are increasing, means that a percentage increase in capital ''K'' and labor ''L'' will produce a larger percentage increase in output ''Y''. Assuming
perfect competition In economics, specifically general equilibrium theory, a perfect market, also known as an atomistic market, is defined by several idealizing conditions, collectively called perfect competition, or atomistic competition. In Economic model, theoret ...
and , and can be shown to be capital's and labor's shares of output. In its generalized form, the Cobb–Douglas function models more than two goods. The Cobb–Douglas function may be written as :f(x)=A \prod_^n x_i^, \qquad x = (x_1, \ldots, x_n). where * ''A'' is an efficiency parameter * ''n'' is the total number of input variables (goods) * are the (non-negative) quantities of good consumed, produced, etc. * \lambda_i is an elasticity parameter for good ''i''


History

Paul Douglas explained that his first formulation of the Cobb–Douglas production function was developed in 1927; when seeking a functional form to relate estimates he had calculated for workers and capital, he spoke with mathematician and colleague Charles Cobb, who suggested a function of the form , previously used by Knut Wicksell, Philip Wicksteed, and
Léon Walras Marie-Esprit-Léon Walras (; 16 December 1834 – 5 January 1910) was a French mathematical economist and Georgist. He formulated the marginal theory of value (independently of William Stanley Jevons and Carl Menger) and pioneered the developmen ...
, although Douglas only acknowledges Wicksteed and Walras for their contributions. Not long after Knut Wicksell's death in 1926, Paul Douglas and Charles Cobb implemented the Cobb-Douglas function in their work covering the subject manner of producer theory for the first time. Estimating this using
least squares The method of least squares is a standard approach in regression analysis to approximate the solution of overdetermined systems (sets of equations in which there are more equations than unknowns) by minimizing the sum of the squares of the res ...
, he obtained a result for the exponent of labour of 0.75—which was subsequently confirmed by the National Bureau of Economic Research to be 0.741. Later work in the 1940s prompted them to allow for the exponents on ''K'' and ''L'' to vary, resulting in estimates that subsequently proved to be very close to improved measure of productivity developed at that time. A major criticism at the time was that estimates of the production function, although seemingly accurate, were based on such sparse data that it was hard to give them much credibility. Douglas remarked "I must admit I was discouraged by this criticism and thought of giving up the effort, but there was something which told me I should hold on." The breakthrough came in using US census data, which was cross-sectional and provided a large number of observations. Douglas presented the results of these findings, along with those for other countries, at his 1947 address as president of the
American Economic Association The American Economic Association (AEA) is a learned society in the field of economics. It publishes several peer-reviewed journals acknowledged in business and academia. There are some 23,000 members. History and Constitution The AEA was esta ...
. Shortly afterwards, Douglas went into politics and was stricken by ill health—resulting in little further development on his side. However, two decades later, his production function was widely used, being adopted by economists such as Paul Samuelson and Robert Solow. The Cobb–Douglas production function is especially notable for being the first time an aggregate or economy-wide production function had been developed, estimated, and then presented to the profession for analysis; it marked a landmark change in how economists approached macroeconomics from a microeconomics perspective.


Criticisms

The function has been criticised for its lack of foundation. Cobb and Douglas were influenced by statistical evidence that appeared to show that labor and capital shares of total output were constant over time in developed countries; they explained this by statistical fitting least-squares regression of their production function. There is now doubt over whether constancy over time exists.. The production function contains a principal assumption that may not always provide the most accurate representation of a country's productive capabilities and supply-side efficiencies. This assumption is a “constant share of labor in output”, which may not be effective when applied to cases of countries whose labor markets are growing at significant rates. Another issue within the fundamental composition the Cobb Douglas production function is the presence of simultaneous equation bias. When competition is presumed the simultaneous equation bias has impact on all function types involving firm decisions – including the Cobb Douglas function. In some cases this simultaneous equation bias doesn't appear. However, it is apparent when least squares asymptotic approximations are used. The Cobb–Douglas production function was not developed on the basis of any knowledge of engineering, technology, or management of the production process. This rationale may be true given the definition of the Capital term. Labor hours and Capital need a better definition. If capital is defined as a building, labor is already included in the development of that building. A building is composed of commodities, labor and risks and general conditions. It was instead developed because it had attractive mathematical characteristics, such as
diminishing marginal returns In economics, diminishing returns are the decrease in marginal (incremental) output of a production process as the amount of a single factor of production is incrementally increased, holding all other factors of production equal (ceteris paribus ...
to either factor of production and the property that the optimal expenditure shares on any given input of a firm operating a Cobb–Douglas technology are constant. Initially, there were no utility foundations for it. In the modern era, some economists try to build models up from individual agents acting, rather than imposing a functional form on an entire economy. The Cobb–Douglas production function, if properly defined, can be applied at a micro-economic level, up to a macro- economic level. However, many modern authors have developed models which give microeconomically based Cobb–Douglas production functions, including many New Keynesian models. It is nevertheless a mathematical mistake to assume that just because the Cobb–Douglas function applies at the microeconomic level, it also always applies at the macroeconomic level. Similarly, it is not necessarily the case that a macro Cobb–Douglas applies at the disaggregated level. An early microfoundation of the aggregate Cobb–Douglas technology based on linear activities is derived in Houthakker (1955). The Cobb–Douglas production function is inconsistent with modern empirical estimates of the elasticity of substitution between capital and labor, which suggest that capital and labor are gross complements. A 2021 meta-analysis of 3186 estimates concludes that "the weight of evidence accumulated in the empirical literature emphatically rejects the Cobb-Douglas specification."


Cobb–Douglas utilities

The Cobb–Douglas function is often used as a utility function. Utility \tilde is a function of the quantities x_i of the L goods consumed: : \tilde(x)= \prod_^n x_i^ Utility functions represent ordinal preferences and do not have natural units, unlike production functions. As the result, a monotonic transformation of a utility function represents the same preferences. Unlike with a Cobb–Douglas production function, where the sum of the exponents determines the degree of economies of scale, the sum can be normalized to one for a utility function because normalization is a monotonic transformation of the original utility function. Thus, let us define \lambda = \sum_^n \lambda_i and \alpha_i = \frac, so \sum_^n \alpha_i = 1, and write the utility function as: :u(x) = \prod_^n x_i^ The consumer maximizes utility subject to the budget constraint that the cost of the goods is less than her wealth w. Letting p_i denote the goods' prices, she solves: : \max_ \prod_^n x_i^ \quad \text \quad \sum_^n p_i x_i= w It turns out that the solution for Cobb-Douglas demand is :\forall j: \qquad x_j^\star=\frac Since \alpha_j = \frac, the consumer spends fraction \alpha_j of her wealth on good . Note that this is the solution for either u(x) or \tilde(x), since the same preferences generate the same demand. The indirect utility function can be calculated by substituting the demands x_j into the utility function. Define the constant K= \Pi_^n \alpha_i^) and we get: : v(p,w) = \prod_^n \left( \frac \right)^ = \frac =K \left(\frac \right) which is a special case of the Gorman polar form. The expenditure function is the inverse of the indirect utility function: :e(p, u) = (1/K)\prod_^n p_i^ u


Various representations of the production function

The Cobb–Douglas function form can be estimated as a linear relationship using the following expression: : \ln(Y) = a_0 + \sum_i a_i \ln(I_i) where * Y = \text * I_i = \text * a_i = \text The model can also be written as : Y = e^ (I_1)^ \cdot (I_2)^ \cdots As noted, the common Cobb–Douglas function used in macroeconomic modeling is : Y = K^\alpha L^\beta where ''K'' is capital and ''L'' is labor. When the model exponents sum to one, the production function is first-order
homogeneous Homogeneity and heterogeneity are concepts often used in the sciences and statistics relating to the uniformity of a substance or organism. A material or image that is homogeneous is uniform in composition or character (i.e. color, shape, siz ...
, which implies constant returns to scale—that is, if all inputs are scaled by a common factor greater than zero, output will be scaled by the same factor.


Relationship to the CES production function

The constant elasticity of substitution (CES) production function (in the two-factor case) is : Y = A \left ( \alpha K^\gamma + (1-\alpha) L^\gamma \right )^, in which the limiting case corresponds to a Cobb–Douglas function, Y=AK^\alpha L^, with constant returns to scale. To see this, the log of the CES function, : \ln(Y) = \ln(A) + \frac \ln \left (\alpha K^\gamma + (1-\alpha) L^\gamma \right ) can be taken to the limit by applying l'Hôpital's rule: : \lim_ \ln(Y) = \ln(A) + \alpha \ln(K) + (1-\alpha) \ln(L). Therefore, Y=AK^\alpha L^.


Translog production function

The translog production function is an approximation of the CES function by a second-order Taylor polynomial in the variable \gamma about \gamma = 0, i.e. the Cobb–Douglas case. The name translog stands for 'transcendental logarithmic'. It is often used in econometrics for the fact that it is linear in the parameters, which means
ordinary least squares In statistics, ordinary least squares (OLS) is a type of linear least squares method for choosing the unknown parameters in a linear regression model (with fixed level-one effects of a linear function of a set of explanatory variables) by the prin ...
could be used if inputs could be assumed exogenous. In the two-factor case above the translog production function is : \begin \ln(Y) &= \ln(A) + \alpha \ln(K) + (1-\alpha) \ln(L) + \frac \gamma \alpha (1 - \alpha) \left \ln(K) - \ln(L) \right2 \\ &= \ln(A) + a_K \ln(K) + a_L \ln(L) + b_ \ln^2(K) + b_ \ln^(L) + b_ \ln(K) \ln(L) \end where a_K, a_L, b_, b_, and b_ are defined appropriately. In the three factor case, the translog production function is: :\begin \ln(Y) & = \ln(A) + a_L\ln(L) + a_K\ln(K) + a_M\ln(M) + b_\ln^2(L) +b_\ln^2(K) + b_\ln^2(M) \\ & \qquad \qquad + b_\ln(L)\ln(K) + b_\ln(L)\ln(M) + b_\ln(K)\ln(M) \\ & = f(L,K,M). \end where A = total factor productivity, L = labor, K = capital, M = materials and supplies, and Y = output.


See also

* Leontief production function *
Production–possibility frontier A production–possibility frontier (PPF), production possibility curve (PPC), or production possibility boundary (PPB), or transformation curve/boundary/frontier is a curve which shows various combinations of the amounts of two goods which can be ...
* Production theory


References


Further reading

*


External links


Anatomy of Cobb-Douglas Type Production Functions in 3D

Analysis of the Cobb-Douglas as a utility function

Closed Form Solution for a firm with an N-input production function
{{DEFAULTSORT:Cobb-Douglas production function Utility function types 1947 in economics Production economics