Category utility is a measure of "category goodness" defined in and . It attempts to maximize both the probability that two objects in the same category have attribute values in common, and the probability that objects from different categories have different attribute values. It was intended to supersede more limited measures of category goodness such as "
cue validity Cue validity is the conditional probability that an object falls in a particular category given a particular feature or ''cue''. The term was popularized by , and especially by Eleanor Rosch in her investigations of the acquisition of so-called Pro ...
" (; ) and "collocation index" . It provides a normative
information-theoretic measure of the ''predictive advantage'' gained by the observer who possesses knowledge of the given category structure (i.e., the class labels of instances) over the observer who does ''not'' possess knowledge of the category structure. In this sense the motivation for the category utility measure is similar to the
information gain metric used in
decision tree
A decision tree is a decision support tool that uses a tree-like model of decisions and their possible consequences, including chance event outcomes, resource costs, and utility. It is one way to display an algorithm that only contains condit ...
learning. In certain presentations, it is also formally equivalent to the
mutual information, as discussed below. A review of category utility in its probabilistic incarnation, with applications to
machine learning, is provided in .
Probability-theoretic definition of category utility
The
probability-theoretic definition of category utility given in and is as follows:
:
where
is a size-
set of
-ary features, and
is a set of
categories. The term
designates the
marginal probability that feature
takes on value
, and the term
designates the category-
conditional probability that feature
takes on value
''given'' that the object in question belongs to category
.
The motivation and development of this expression for category utility, and the role of the multiplicand
as a crude overfitting control, is given in the above sources. Loosely , the term
is the expected number of attribute values that can be correctly guessed by an observer using a
probability-matching
Probability matching is a decision strategy in which predictions of class membership are proportional to the class base rates. Thus, if in the training set positive examples are observed 60% of the time, and negative examples are observed 40% of t ...
strategy together with knowledge of the category labels, while
is the expected number of attribute values that can be correctly guessed by an observer the same strategy but without any knowledge of the category labels. Their difference therefore reflects the relative advantage accruing to the observer by having knowledge of the category structure.
Information-theoretic definition of category utility
The
information-theoretic definition of category utility for a set of entities with size-
binary feature set
, and a binary category
is given in as follows:
:
where
is the
prior probability of an entity belonging to the positive category
(in the absence of any feature information),
is the conditional probability of an entity having feature
given that the entity belongs to category
,
is likewise the conditional probability of an entity having feature
given that the entity belongs to category
, and
is the prior probability of an entity possessing feature
(in the absence of any category information).
The intuition behind the above expression is as follows: The term
represents the cost (in bits) of optimally encoding (or transmitting) feature information when it is known that the objects to be described belong to category
. Similarly, the term
represents the cost (in bits) of optimally encoding (or transmitting) feature information when it is known that the objects to be described belong to category
. The sum of these two terms in the brackets is therefore the
weighted average of these two costs. The final term,
, represents the cost (in bits) of optimally encoding (or transmitting) feature information when no category information is available. The value of the category utility will, in the above formulation, be negative (???).
Category utility and mutual information
and mention that the category utility is equivalent to the
mutual information. Here is a simple demonstration of the nature of this equivalence. Assume a set of entities each having the same
features, i.e., feature set
, with each feature variable having cardinality
. That is, each feature has the capacity to adopt any of
distinct values (which need ''not'' be ordered; all variables can be nominal); for the special case
these features would be considered ''binary'', but more generally, for any
, the features are simply ''m-ary''. For the purposes of this demonstration, without loss of generality, feature set
can be replaced with a single aggregate variable
that has cardinality
, and adopts a unique value
corresponding to each feature combination in the
Cartesian product
In mathematics, specifically set theory, the Cartesian product of two sets ''A'' and ''B'', denoted ''A''×''B'', is the set of all ordered pairs where ''a'' is in ''A'' and ''b'' is in ''B''. In terms of set-builder notation, that is
: A\ti ...
. (Ordinality does ''not'' matter, because the mutual information is not sensitive to ordinality.) In what follows, a term such as
or simply
refers to the probability with which
adopts the particular value
. (Using the aggregate feature variable
replaces multiple summations, and simplifies the presentation to follow.)
For this demonstration, also assume a single category variable
, which has cardinality
. This is equivalent to a classification system in which there are
non-intersecting categories. In the special case of
there are the two-category case discussed above. From the definition of mutual information for discrete variables, the mutual information
between the aggregate feature variable
and the category variable
is given by:
:
where
is the
prior probability of feature variable
adopting value
,
is the
marginal probability of category variable
adopting value
, and
is the
joint probability of variables
and
simultaneously adopting those respective values. In terms of the conditional probabilities this can be re-written (or defined) as
:
If the original
definition of the category utility from above is rewritten with
,
:
This equation clearly has the same form as the (
blue) equation expressing the mutual information between the feature set and the category variable; the difference is that the sum
in the category utility equation runs over independent
binary variables
Binary data is data whose unit can take on only two possible states. These are often labelled as 0 and 1 in accordance with the binary numeral system and Boolean algebra.
Binary data occurs in many different technical and scientific fields, wher ...
, whereas the sum
in the mutual information runs over ''values'' of the single
-ary variable
. The two measures are actually equivalent then ''only'' when the features
, are ''independent'' (and assuming that terms in the sum corresponding to
are also added).
Insensitivity of category utility to ordinality
Like the mutual information, the category utility is not sensitive to any ''ordering'' in the feature or category variable values. That is, as far as the category utility is concerned, the category set
is not qualitatively different from the category set
since the formulation of the category utility does not account for any ordering of the class variable. Similarly, a feature variable adopting values
is not qualitatively different from a feature variable adopting values
. As far as the category utility or ''mutual information'' are concerned, ''all'' category and feature variables are ''nominal variables.'' For this reason, category utility does not reflect any ''
gestalt'' aspects of "category goodness" that might be based on such ordering effects. One possible adjustment for this insensitivity to ordinality is given by the weighting scheme described in the article for
mutual information.
Category "goodness": models and philosophy
This section provides some background on the origins of, and need for, formal measures of "category goodness" such as the category utility, and some of the history that lead to the development of this particular metric.
What makes a good category?
At least since the time of
Aristotle there has been a tremendous fascination in philosophy with the nature of
concepts and
universals. What kind of ''entity'' is a concept such as "horse"? Such abstractions do not designate any particular individual in the world, and yet we can scarcely imagine being able to comprehend the world without their use. Does the concept "horse" therefore have an independent existence outside of the mind? If it does, then what is the locus of this independent existence? The question of locus was an important issue on which the classical schools of
Plato and
Aristotle famously differed. However, they remained in agreement that universals ''did'' indeed have a mind-independent existence. There was, therefore, always a ''fact to the matter'' about which concepts and universals exist in the world.
In the late
Middle Ages (perhaps beginning with
Occam, although
Porphyry also makes a much earlier remark indicating a certain discomfort with the status quo), however, the certainty that existed on this issue began to erode, and it became acceptable among the so-called
nominalists
In metaphysics, nominalism is the view that universals and abstract objects do not actually exist other than being merely names or labels. There are at least two main versions of nominalism. One version denies the existence of universalsthings th ...
and
empiricists to consider concepts and universals as strictly mental entities or conventions of language. On this view of concepts—that they are purely representational constructs—a new question then comes to the fore: "Why do we possess one set of concepts rather than another?" What makes one set of concepts "good" and another set of concepts "bad"? This is a question that modern philosophers, and subsequently
machine learning theorists and cognitive scientists, have struggled with for many decades.
What purpose do concepts serve?
One approach to answering such questions is to investigate the "role" or "purpose" of concepts in cognition. Thus the answer to "What are concepts good for in the first place?" by and many others is that classification (conception) is a precursor to ''
induction'': By imposing a particular categorization on the universe, an organism gains the ability to deal with physically non-identical objects or situations in an identical fashion, thereby gaining substantial predictive leverage (; ). As
J.S. Mill puts it ,
From this base,
Mill reaches the following conclusion, which foreshadows much subsequent thinking about category goodness, including the notion of category utility:
One may compare this to the "category utility hypothesis" proposed by : "A category is useful to the extent that it can be expected to improve the ability of a person to accurately predict the features of instances of that category." Mill here seems to be suggesting that the best category structure is one in which object features (properties) are maximally informative about the object's class, and, simultaneously, the object class is maximally informative about the object's features. In other words, a useful classification scheme is one in which category knowledge can be used to accurately infer object properties, and property knowledge can be used to accurately infer object classes. One may also compare this idea to
Aristotle's criterion of ''counter-predication'' for definitional predicates, as well as to the notion of concepts described in
formal concept analysis.
Attempts at formalization
A variety of different measures have been suggested with an aim of formally capturing this notion of "category goodness," the best known of which is probably the "
cue validity Cue validity is the conditional probability that an object falls in a particular category given a particular feature or ''cue''. The term was popularized by , and especially by Eleanor Rosch in her investigations of the acquisition of so-called Pro ...
". Cue validity of a feature
with respect to category
is defined as the conditional probability of the category given the feature (;;),
, or as the deviation of the conditional probability from the category base rate (;),
. Clearly, these measures quantify only inference from feature to category (i.e., ''cue validity''), but not from category to feature, i.e., the ''category validity''
. Also, while the cue validity was originally intended to account for the demonstrable appearance of ''
basic categories In cognitive psychology, a basic category is a category at a particular level of the category inclusion hierarchy (i.e., a particular level of generality) that is preferred by humans in learning and memory tasks. The term is associated with the wor ...
'' in human cognition—categories of a particular level of generality that are evidently preferred by human learners—a number of major flaws in the cue validity quickly emerged in this regard (;;, and others).
One attempt to address both problems by simultaneously maximizing both feature validity and category validity was made by in defining the "collocation index" as the product
, but this construction was fairly ad hoc (see ). The category utility was introduced as a more sophisticated refinement of the cue validity, which attempts to more rigorously quantify the full inferential power of a class structure. As shown above, on a certain view the category utility is equivalent to the mutual information between the feature variable and the category variable. It has been suggested that categories having the greatest overall category utility are those that are not only those "best" in a normative sense, but also those human learners prefer to use, e.g., "basic" categories . Other related measures of category goodness are "cohesion" (;) and "salience" .
Applications
* Category utilility is used as the category evaluation measure in the popular
conceptual clustering algorithm called COBWEB .
See also
*
Abstraction
*
Concept learning
*
Universals
*
Unsupervised learning
References
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
* .
*
*
*
*
*
*
{{refend
Category utility
Category utility is a measure of "category goodness" defined in and . It attempts to maximize both the probability that two objects in the same category have attribute values in common, and the probability that objects from different categories ha ...
Category utility
Category utility is a measure of "category goodness" defined in and . It attempts to maximize both the probability that two objects in the same category have attribute values in common, and the probability that objects from different categories ha ...