Reversal symmetry
   HOME

TheInfoList



OR:

The reversal symmetry criterion is a voting system criterion which says that if every voter's opinions on each of the candidates is perfectly reversed (i.e. they rank candidates in order from worst to best), the outcome of the election should be reversed as well, i.e. the first- and last-place finishers should switch places. In other words, the results of the election should not depend arbitrarily on whether voters rank candidates from best to worst (and then select the best candidate), or whether we ask them to rank candidates from worst to best (and then select the least-bad candidate). Another, equivalent way to motivate the criterion is to say that a voting system should never elect the worst candidate, according to the method itself (as doing so suggests the method is, in some sense, self-contradictory). The worst candidate can be identified by reversing all ballots (to rank candidates from worst-to-best) and then running the algorithm to find a single worst candidate. Situations where the same candidate is elected when all ballots are reversed are sometimes called best-is-worst paradoxes, and can occur in
instant-runoff voting Instant-runoff voting (IRV; ranked-choice voting (RCV), preferential voting, alternative vote) is a single-winner ranked voting election system where Sequential loser method, one or more eliminations are used to simulate Runoff (election), ...
and
minimax Minimax (sometimes Minmax, MM or saddle point) is a decision rule used in artificial intelligence, decision theory, combinatorial game theory, statistics, and philosophy for ''minimizing'' the possible loss function, loss for a Worst-case scenari ...
. Methods that satisfy reversal symmetry include the
Borda count The Borda method or order of merit is a positional voting rule that gives each candidate a number of points equal to the number of candidates ranked below them: the lowest-ranked candidate gets 0 points, the second-lowest gets 1 point, and so on ...
, ranked pairs, Kemeny–Young, and
Schulze Schulze is a German surname, from the medieval office of Schulze, or village official. Notable people with the surname include: * Andrew Schulze (1896–1982), clergyman and civil rights activist * William August Schulze, rocket scientist recru ...
. Most
rated voting Rated, evaluative, graded, or cardinal voting rules are a class of voting methods that allow voters to state how strongly they support a candidate, by giving each one a grade on a separate scale. The distribution of ratings for each candidate ...
systems, including approval and
score voting Score voting, sometimes called range voting, is an electoral system for single-seat elections. Voters give each candidate a numerical score, and the candidate with the highest average score is elected. Score voting includes the well-known approva ...
, satisfy the criterion as well.


Examples


Instant-runoff voting

Consider a preferential system where 11 voters express their preferences as: *5 voters prefer A then B then C *4 voters prefer B then C then A *2 voters prefer C then A then B With the Borda count A would get 23 points (5×3+4×1+2×2), B would get 24 points, and C would get 19 points, so B would be elected. In instant-runoff, C would be eliminated in the first round and A would be elected in the second round by 7 votes to 4. Now reversing the preferences: *5 voters prefer C then B then A *4 voters prefer A then C then B *2 voters prefer B then A then C With the Borda count A would get 21 points (5×1+4×3+2×2), B would get 20 points, and C would get 25 points, so this time C would be elected. In instant-runoff, B would be eliminated in the first round and A would as before be elected in the second round, this time by 6 votes to 5.


Minimax

This example shows that the Minimax method violates the Reversal symmetry criterion. Assume four candidates A, B, C and D with 14 voters with the following preferences: Since all preferences are strict rankings (no equals are present), all three Minimax methods (winning votes, margins and pairwise opposite) elect the same winners. Now, the winners are determined for the normal and the reversed order.


Normal order

The results would be tabulated as follows: * indicates voters who preferred the candidate listed in the column caption to the candidate listed in the row caption * indicates voters who preferred the candidate listed in the row caption to the candidate listed in the column caption Result: The candidates A, B, and C form a cycle with clear defeats. D benefits from that since its two losses are relatively close and therefore D's biggest defeat is the closest of all candidates. Thus, D is elected Minimax winner.


Reversed order

The results would be tabulated as follows: Result: The candidates A, B, and C still form a cycle with clear defeats. Therefore D's biggest defeat is the closest of all candidates, and D is elected Minimax winner.


Conclusion

D is the Minimax winner using the normal preference order and also using the ballots with reversed preference orders. Thus, Minimax fails the reversal symmetry criterion.


Plurality voting

This example shows that plurality voting violates the Reversal symmetry criterion. Assume three candidates A, B and C and 4 voters with the following preferences: Note that reversing all the ballots, leads to the same set of ballots, since the reversed preference order of the first voter resembles the preference order of the second, and similarly with the third and fourth. In the following the Plurality winner is determined. Plurality ballots only contain the single favorite: Result: The candidates A and B receive 1 vote each, candidate C receives a plurality of 2 votes (50%). Thus, C is elected Plurality winner. C is the Plurality winner using the normal ballots and also using the reversed ballot. Thus, Plurality fails the reversal symmetry criterion. Note that every voting system that satisfies the reversal symmetry criterion would have to lead to a tie in this example (as in every example in which the set of reversed ballots is the same as the set of normal ballots).


STAR voting

This example shows STAR violates the reversal symmetry criterion. In a score ballot, reversed score is calculated as the maximum possible score minus the normal score.


Normal score

Given a 3-candidate election between candidates A, B, and C: The results are tabulated below: Result: In the election, candidates A and B have the highest scores, and advance to the runoff round. B wins being preferred over A 3 votes to 2.


Reversed score

Reversing the ballots by subtracting each score from 5 (the maximum score in STAR) gives the following: The results are tabulated below: Result: In the reversed ballots, B and C have the highest total score, and B wins being preferred to C 3 votes to 2.


References

{{Voting systems Electoral system criteria