Price elasticity of demand
   HOME

TheInfoList



OR:

A good's price elasticity of demand (E_d, PED) is a measure of how sensitive the quantity demanded is to its price. When the price rises, quantity demanded falls for almost any good, but it falls more for some than for others. The price elasticity gives the percentage change in quantity demanded when there is a one percent increase in price, holding everything else constant. If the elasticity is −2, that means a one percent price rise leads to a two percent decline in quantity demanded. Other elasticities measure how the quantity demanded changes with other variables (e.g. the
income elasticity of demand In economics, the income elasticity of demand is the responsivenesses of the quantity demanded for a good to a change in consumer income. It is measured as the ratio of the percentage change in quantity demanded to the percentage change in incom ...
for consumer income changes). Price elasticities are negative except in special cases. If a good is said to have an elasticity of 2, it almost always means that the good has an elasticity of −2 according to the formal definition. The phrase "more elastic" means that a good's elasticity has greater magnitude, ignoring the sign. Veblen and
Giffen good In economics and consumer theory, a Giffen good is a product that people consume more of as the price rises and vice versa—violating the basic law of demand in microeconomics. For any other sort of good, as the price of the good rises, the sub ...
s are two classes of goods which have positive elasticity, rare exceptions to the
law of demand In microeconomics, the law of demand is a fundamental principle which states that there is an inverse relationship between price and quantity demanded. In other words, "conditional on all else being equal, as the price of a good increases (↑), ...
. Demand for a good is said to be ''inelastic'' when the elasticity is less than one in absolute value: that is, changes in price have a relatively small effect on the quantity demanded. Demand for a good is said to be ''elastic'' when the elasticity is greater than one. A good with an elasticity of −2 has elastic demand because quantity falls twice as much as the price increase; an elasticity of −0.5 has inelastic demand because the quantity response is half the price increase. At an elasticity of 0 consumption would not change at all, in spite of any price increases. Revenue is maximised when price is set so that the elasticity is exactly one. The good's elasticity can be used to predict the incidence (or "burden") of a tax on that good. Various research methods are used to determine price elasticity, including
test market A test market, in the field of business and marketing, is a geographic region or demographic group used to gauge the viability of a product or service in the mass market prior to a wide scale roll-out. The criteria used to judge the acceptabilit ...
s, analysis of historical sales data and
conjoint analysis Conjoint analysis is a survey-based statistical technique used in market research that helps determine how people value different attributes (feature, function, benefits) that make up an individual product or service. The objective of conjoint an ...
.


Definition

The variation in demand in response to a variation in price is called price elasticity of demand. It may also be defined as the
ratio In mathematics, a ratio shows how many times one number contains another. For example, if there are eight oranges and six lemons in a bowl of fruit, then the ratio of oranges to lemons is eight to six (that is, 8:6, which is equivalent to the ...
of the percentage change in quantity demanded to the percentage change in price of particular commodity.Png, Ivan (1989). p. 57. The formula for the coefficient of price elasticity of demand for a good is:Gillespie, Andrew (2007). p. 43.Gwartney, Yaw Bugyei-Kyei.James D.; Stroup, Richard L.; Sobel, Russell S. (2008). p. 425. :E_ = \frac where P is the price of the good demanded, \Delta P is how much it changed, Q is the quantity of the good demanded, and \Delta Q is how much it changed. In other words, we can say that the price elasticity of demand is the percentage change in demand for a commodity due to a given percentage change in the price. If the quantity demanded falls 20 tons from an initial 200 tons after the price rises $5 from an initial price of $100, then the quantity demanded has fallen 10% and the price has risen 5%, so the elasticity is (−10%)/(+5%) = −2. The price elasticity of demand is ordinarily negative because quantity demanded falls when price rises, as described by the "law of demand". Two rare classes of goods which have elasticity greater than 0 (consumers buy more if the price is ''higher'') are Veblen and Giffen goods.Gillespie, Andrew (2007). p. 57. Since the price elasticity of demand is negative for the vast majority of goods and services (unlike most other elasticities, which take both positive and negative values depending on the good), economists often leave off the word "negative" or the minus sign and refer to the price elasticity of demand as a positive value (i.e., in absolute value terms). They will say "Yachts have an elasticity of two" meaning the elasticity is −2. This is a common source of confusion for students. Depending on its elasticity, a good is said to have elastic demand (> 1), inelastic demand (< 1), or unitary elastic demand (= 1). If demand is elastic, the quantity demanded is very sensitive to price, e.g. when a 1% rise in price generates a 10% decrease in quantity. If demand is inelastic, the good's demand is relatively insensitive to price, with quantity changing less than price. If demand is unitary elastic, the quantity falls by exactly the percentage that the price rises. Two important special cases are perfectly elastic demand (= ∞), where even a small rise in price reduces the quantity demanded to zero; and perfectly inelastic demand (= 0), where a rise in price leaves the quantity unchanged. The above measure of elasticity is sometimes referred to as the ''own-price'' elasticity of demand for a good, i.e., the elasticity of demand with respect to the good's own price, in order to distinguish it from the elasticity of demand for that good with respect to the change in the price of some other good, i.e., an independent, complementary, or substitute good. That two-good type of elasticity is called a ''cross''-price elasticity of demand. If a 1% rise in the price of gasoline causes a 0.5% fall in the quantity of cars demanded, the cross-price elasticity is E^d_ = (-0.5%)/(+1%) = -0.5. As the size of the price change gets bigger, the elasticity definition becomes less reliable for a combination of two reasons. First, a good's elasticity is not necessarily constant; it varies at different points along the demand curve because a 1% change in price has a quantity effect that may depend on whether the initial price is high or low. Contrary to
common misconception Each entry on this list of common misconceptions is worded as a correction; the misconceptions themselves are implied rather than stated. These entries are concise summaries of the main subject articles, which can be consulted for more detail. ...
, the price elasticity is not constant even along a linear demand curve, but rather varies along the curve. A linear demand curve's slope is constant, to be sure, but the elasticity can change even if \Delta P/\Delta Q is constant.Parkin; Powell; Matthews (2002). p .75. There does exist a nonlinear shape of demand curve along which the elasticity is constant: P = aQ^, where a is a shift constant and E is the elasticity. Second, percentage changes are not symmetric; instead, the percentage change between any two values depends on which one is chosen as the starting value and which as the ending value. For example, suppose that when the price rises from $10 to $16, the quantity falls from 100 units to 80. This is a price increase of 60% and a quantity decline of 20%, an elasticity of (-20%)/(+60%) \approx -0.33 for that part of the demand curve. If the price falls from $16 to $10 and the quantity rises from 80 units to 100, however, the price decline is 37.5% and the quantity gain is 25%, an elasticity of (+25%)/(-37.5%) = -0.67 for the same part of the curve. This is an example of the index number problem.Ruffin; Gregory (1988). pp. 518–519.Ferguson, C.E. (1972). pp. 100–101. Two refinements of the definition of elasticity are used to deal with these shortcomings of the basic elasticity formula: ''arc elasticity'' and ''point elasticity''.


Arc elasticity

Arc elasticity was introduced very early on by Hugh Dalton. It is very similar to an ordinary elasticity problem, but it adds in the index number problem. Arc Elasticity is a second solution to the asymmetry problem of having an elasticity dependent on which of the two given points on a demand curve is chosen as the "original" point will and which as the "new" one is to compute the percentage change in P and Q relative to the ''average'' of the two prices and the ''average'' of the two quantities, rather than just the change relative to one point or the other. Loosely speaking, this gives an "average" elasticity for the section of the actual demand curve—i.e., the ''arc'' of the curve—between the two points. As a result, this measure is known as the ''
arc elasticity In mathematics and economics, the arc elasticity is the elasticity of one variable with respect to another between two given points. It is the ratio of the percentage change of one of the variables between the two points to the percentage change of ...
'', in this case with respect to the price of the good. The arc elasticity is defined mathematically as:Wall, Stuart; Griffiths, Alan (2008). pp. 53–54.McConnell;Brue (1990). pp. 434–435. :E_d = \frac\times\frac = \frac\times\frac This method for computing the price elasticity is also known as the "midpoints formula", because the average price and average quantity are the coordinates of the midpoint of the straight line between the two given points. This formula is an application of the
midpoint method In numerical analysis, a branch of applied mathematics, the midpoint method is a one-step method for numerically solving the differential equation, : y'(t) = f(t, y(t)), \quad y(t_0) = y_0 . The explicit midpoint method is given by the formula ...
. However, because this formula implicitly assumes the section of the demand curve between those points is linear, the greater the curvature of the actual demand curve is over that range, the worse this approximation of its elasticity will be.


Point elasticity

The point elasticity of demand method is used to determine change in demand within the same demand curve, basically a very small amount of change in demand is measured through point elasticity. One way to avoid the accuracy problem described above is to minimize the difference between the starting and ending prices and quantities. This is the approach taken in the definition of ''point'' elasticity, which uses differential calculus to calculate the elasticity for an infinitesimal change in price and quantity at any given point on the demand curve:Sloman, John (2006). p. 55. :E_d = \frac \times \frac In other words, it is equal to the absolute value of the first derivative of quantity with respect to price \frac multiplied by the point's price (''P'') divided by its quantity (''Q''d).Wessels, Walter J. (2000). p. 296. However, the point elasticity can be computed only if the formula for the
demand function In economics, a demand curve is a graph depicting the relationship between the price of a certain commodity (the ''y''-axis) and the quantity of that commodity that is demanded at that price (the ''x''-axis). Demand curves can be used either for ...
, Q_d = f(P), is known so its derivative with respect to price, , can be determined. In terms of partial-differential calculus, point elasticity of demand can be defined as follows: let \displaystyle x(p,w) be the demand of goods x_1,x_2,\dots,x_L as a function of parameters price and wealth, and let \displaystyle x_\ell(p,w) be the demand for good \displaystyle\ell. The elasticity of demand for good \displaystyle x_\ell(p,w) with respect to price p_k is :E_ = \frac\cdot\frac = \frac


History

Together with the concept of an economic "elasticity" coefficient, Alfred Marshall is credited with defining "elasticity of demand" in '' Principles of Economics'', published in 1890. Alfred Marshall invented price elasticity of demand only four years after he had invented the concept of elasticity. He used Cournot's basic creating of the demand curve to get the equation for price elasticity of demand. He described price elasticity of demand as thus: "And we may say generally:— the elasticity (or responsiveness) of demand in a market is great or small according as the amount demanded increases much or little for a given fall in price, and diminishes much or little for a given rise in price". He reasons this since "the only universal law as to a person's desire for a commodity is that it diminishes ... but this diminution may be slow or rapid. If it is slow... a small fall in price will cause a comparatively large increase in his purchases. But if it is rapid, a small fall in price will cause only a very small increase in his purchases. In the former case... the elasticity of his wants, we may say, is great. In the latter case... the elasticity of his demand is small." Mathematically, the Marshallian PED was based on a point-price definition, using differential calculus to calculate elasticities.


Determinants

The overriding factor in determining the elasticity is the willingness and ability of consumers after a price change to postpone immediate consumption decisions concerning the good and to search for substitutes ("wait and look").Negbennebor (2001). A number of factors can thus affect the elasticity of demand for a good:Parkin; Powell; Matthews (2002). pp. 77–9. ; Availability of substitute goods: The more and closer the substitutes available, the higher the elasticity is likely to be, as people can easily switch from one good to another if an even minor price change is made;Goodwin, Nelson, Ackerman, & Weisskopf (2009). There is a strong substitution effect.Frank (2008) 118. If no close substitutes are available, the substitution effect will be small and the demand inelastic. ; Breadth of definition of a good: The broader the definition of a good (or service), the lower the elasticity. For example, Company X's fish and chips would tend to have a relatively high elasticity of demand if a significant number of substitutes are available, whereas food in general would have an extremely low elasticity of demand because no substitutes exist.Gillespie, Andrew (2007). p. 48. Specifical foodstuffs (Ice cream, meat, spinach) or families of them (dairy, meat, sea products) may be more elastic. ; Percentage of income: The higher the percentage of the consumer's income that the product's price represents, the higher the elasticity tends to be, as people will pay more attention when purchasing the good because of its cost; The income effect is substantial.Frank (2008) 119. When the goods represent only a negligible portion of the budget the income effect will be insignificant and demand inelastic, ; Necessity: The more necessary a good is, the lower the elasticity, as people will attempt to buy it no matter the price, such as the case of insulin for those who need it. ; Duration: For most goods, the longer a price change holds, the higher the elasticity is likely to be, as more and more consumers find they have the time and inclination to search for substitutes. When fuel prices increase suddenly, for instance, consumers may still fill up their empty tanks in the short run, but when prices remain high over several years, more consumers will reduce their demand for fuel by switching to
carpool Carpooling (also car-sharing, ride-sharing and lift-sharing) is the sharing of Automobile, car journeys so that more than one person travels in a car, and prevents the need for others to have to drive to a location themselves. By having more ...
ing or public transportation, investing in vehicles with greater fuel economy or taking other measures. This does not hold for
consumer durable In economics, a durable good or a hard good or consumer durable is a good that does not quickly wear out or, more specifically, one that yields utility over time rather than being completely consumed in one use. Items like bricks could be consi ...
s such as the cars themselves, however; eventually, it may become necessary for consumers to replace their present cars, so one would expect demand to be less elastic. ; Brand loyalty: An attachment to a certain brand—either out of tradition or because of proprietary barriers—can override sensitivity to price changes, resulting in more inelastic demand.Png, Ivan (1999). pp. 62–3. ; Who pays: Where the purchaser does not directly pay for the good they consume, such as with corporate expense accounts, demand is likely to be more inelastic. Addictiveness Goods that are more addictive in nature tend to have an inelastic PED (absolute value of PED < 1). Examples of such include cigarettes, heroin and alcohol. This is because consumers treat such goods as necessities and hence are forced to purchase them, despite even significant price changes.


Relation to marginal revenue

The following equation holds: : R' = P \, \left( 1 + \dfrac \right) where : ''R''′ is the
marginal revenue Marginal revenue (or marginal benefit) is a central concept in microeconomics that describes the additional total revenue generated by increasing product sales by 1 unit.Bradley R. chiller, "Essentials of Economics", New York: McGraw-Hill, Inc., ...
: ''P'' is the price Proof: : Define Total Revenue as ''R'' : R' = \frac = \frac (P \, Q) = P + Q \, \frac : E_d = \dfrac \cdot \dfrac \Rightarrow E_d \cdot \frac = \frac \Rightarrow \frac = \frac : R' = P + Q \cdot \frac = P \, \left( 1 + \frac \right) On a graph with both a demand curve and a marginal revenue curve, demand will be elastic at all quantities where marginal revenue is positive. Demand is unit elastic at the quantity where marginal revenue is zero. Demand is inelastic at every quantity where marginal revenue is negative.


Effect on entire revenue

A firm considering a price change must know what effect the change in price will have on total revenue. Revenue is simply the product of unit price times quantity: : \text = PQ_d Generally, any change in price will have two effects: ;The price effect: For inelastic goods, an increase in unit price will tend to increase revenue, while a decrease in price will tend to decrease revenue. (The effect is reversed for elastic goods.) ;The quantity effect: An increase in unit price will tend to lead to fewer units sold, while a decrease in unit price will tend to lead to more units sold. For inelastic goods, because of the inverse nature of the relationship between price and quantity demanded (i.e., the law of demand), the two effects affect total revenue in opposite directions. But in determining whether to increase or decrease prices, a firm needs to know what the net effect will be. Elasticity provides the answer: The percentage change in total revenue is approximately equal to the percentage change in quantity demanded plus the percentage change in price. (One change will be positive, the other negative.) The percentage change in quantity is related to the percentage change in price by elasticity: hence the percentage change in revenue can be calculated by knowing the elasticity and the percentage change in price alone. As a result, the relationship between elasticity and revenue can be described for any good:Arnold, Roger (2008). p. 385. * When the price elasticity of demand for a
good In most contexts, the concept of good denotes the conduct that should be preferred when posed with a choice between possible actions. Good is generally considered to be the opposite of evil and is of interest in the study of ethics, morality, ph ...
is ''perfectly inelastic'' (''E''''d'' = 0), changes in the price do not affect the quantity demanded for the good; raising prices will always cause total revenue to increase. Goods necessary to survival can be classified here; a rational person will be willing to pay anything for a good if the alternative is death. For example, a person in the desert weak and dying of thirst would easily give all the money in his wallet, no matter how much, for a bottle of water if he would otherwise die. His demand is not contingent on the price. * When the price elasticity of demand is ''relatively inelastic'' (−1 < ''E''''d'' < 0), the percentage change in quantity demanded is smaller than that in price. Hence, when the price is raised, the total revenue increases, and vice versa. * When the price elasticity of demand is ''unit (or unitary) elastic'' (''E''''d'' = −1), the percentage change in quantity demanded is equal to that in price, so a change in price will not affect total revenue. * When the price elasticity of demand is ''relatively elastic'' (−∞ < ''E''''d'' < −1), the percentage change in quantity demanded is greater than that in price. Hence, when the price is raised, the total revenue falls, and vice versa. * When the price elasticity of demand is ''perfectly elastic'' (''E''''d'' is −
The infinity symbol (\infty) is a List of mathematical symbols, mathematical symbol representing the concept of infinity. This symbol is also called a lemniscate, after the lemniscate curves of a similar shape studied in algebraic geometry, or ...
), any increase in the price, no matter how small, will cause the quantity demanded for the good to drop to zero. Hence, when the price is raised, the total revenue falls to zero. This situation is typical for goods that have their value defined by law (such as fiat currency); if a five-dollar bill were sold for anything more than five dollars, nobody would buy it nless there is demand for economical jokes so demand is zero (assuming that the bill does not have a misprint or something else which would cause it to have its own inherent value). Hence, as the accompanying diagram shows, total revenue is maximized at the combination of price and quantity demanded where the elasticity of demand is unitary. It is important to realize that price-elasticity of demand is ''not'' necessarily constant over all price ranges. The linear demand curve in the accompanying diagram illustrates that changes in price also change the elasticity: the price elasticity is different at every point on the curve.


Effect on tax incidence

Demand elasticity, in combination with the
price elasticity of supply The price elasticity of supply (PES or Es) is a measure used in economics to show the responsiveness, or elasticity, of the quantity supplied of a good or service to a change in its price. The elasticity is represented in numerical form, and ...
can be used to assess where the incidence (or "burden") of a per-unit tax is falling or to predict where it will fall if the tax is imposed. For example, when demand is ''perfectly inelastic'', by definition consumers have no alternative to purchasing the good or service if the price increases, so the quantity demanded would remain constant. Hence, suppliers can increase the price by the full amount of the tax, and the consumer would end up paying the entirety. In the opposite case, when demand is ''perfectly elastic'', by definition consumers have an infinite ability to switch to alternatives if the price increases, so they would stop buying the good or service in question completely—quantity demanded would fall to zero. As a result, firms cannot pass on any part of the tax by raising prices, so they would be forced to pay all of it themselves.Wall, Stuart; Griffiths, Alan (2008). pp. 57–58. In practice, demand is likely to be only ''relatively'' elastic or relatively inelastic, that is, somewhere between the extreme cases of perfect elasticity or inelasticity. More generally, then, the ''higher'' the elasticity of demand compared to PES, the heavier the burden on producers; conversely, the more ''inelastic'' the demand compared to supply, the heavier the burden on consumers. The general principle is that the party (i.e., consumers or producers) that has ''fewer'' opportunities to avoid the tax by switching to alternatives will bear the ''greater'' proportion of the tax burden. In the end the whole tax burden is carried by individual households since they are the ultimate owners of the means of production that the firm utilises (see Circular flow of income). PED and PES can also have an effect on the deadweight loss associated with a tax regime. When PED, PES or both are inelastic, the deadweight loss is lower than a comparable scenario with higher elasticity.


Optimal pricing

Among the most common applications of price elasticity is to determine prices that maximize revenue or profit.


Constant elasticity and optimal pricing

If one point elasticity is used to model demand changes over a finite range of prices, elasticity is implicitly assumed constant with respect to price over the finite price range. The equation defining price elasticity for one product can be rewritten (omitting secondary variables) as a linear equation. :LQ = K + E \times LP where :LQ = \ln(Q), LP = \ln(P), E is the elasticity, and K is a constant. Similarly, the equations for cross elasticity for n products can be written as a set of n simultaneous linear equations. :LQ_\ell = K_\ell + E_ \times LP^k where :\ell and k= 1, \dotsc, n,\,\, LQ_\ell = \ln(Q_\ell), LP^\ell = \ln(P^\ell), and K_\ell are constants; and appearance of a letter index as both an upper index and a lower index in the same term implies summation over that index. This form of the equations shows that point elasticities assumed constant over a price range cannot determine what prices generate maximum values of \ln(Q); similarly they cannot predict prices that generate maximum Q or maximum revenue. Constant elasticities can predict optimal pricing only by computing point elasticities at several points, to determine the price at which point elasticity equals −1 (or, for multiple products, the set of prices at which the point elasticity matrix is the negative identity matrix).


Non-constant elasticity and optimal pricing

If the definition of price elasticity is extended to yield a quadratic relationship between demand units (Q) and price, then it is possible to compute prices that maximize \ln(Q), Q, and revenue. The fundamental equation for one product becomes :LQ = K + E_1 \times LP + E_2 \times LP^2 and the corresponding equation for several products becomes :LQ_\ell = K_\ell + E1_ \times LP^k + E2_ \times (LP^k)^2 Excel models are available that compute constant elasticity, and use non-constant elasticity to estimate prices that optimize revenue or profit for one product or several products.


Limitations of revenue-maximizing strategies

In most situations, such as those with nonzero variable costs, revenue-maximizing prices are not profit-maximizing prices. For these situations, using a technique for Profit maximization is more appropriate.


Selected price elasticities

Various research methods are used to calculate the price elasticities in real life, including analysis of historic sales data, both public and private, and use of present-day surveys of customers' preferences to build up test markets capable of modelling such changes. Alternatively,
conjoint analysis Conjoint analysis is a survey-based statistical technique used in market research that helps determine how people value different attributes (feature, function, benefits) that make up an individual product or service. The objective of conjoint an ...
(a ranking of users' preferences which can then be statistically analysed) may be used. Approximate estimates of price elasticity can be calculated from the
income elasticity of demand In economics, the income elasticity of demand is the responsivenesses of the quantity demanded for a good to a change in consumer income. It is measured as the ratio of the percentage change in quantity demanded to the percentage change in incom ...
, under conditions of preference independence. This approach has been empirically validated using bundles of goods (e.g. food, healthcare, education, recreation, etc.). Though elasticities for most demand schedules vary depending on price, they can be modeled assuming constant elasticity. Using this method, the elasticities for various goods—intended to act as examples of the theory described above—are as follows. For suggestions on why these goods and services may have the elasticity shown, see the above section on determinants of price elasticity. * Cigarettes (US)Perloff, J. (2008). p. 97. ** −0.3 to −0.6 (general) ** −0.6 to −0.7 (youth) * Alcoholic beverages (US) **−0.3 or −0.7 to −0.9 as of 1972 (beer) **−1.0 (wine) **−1.5 (spirits) * Airline travel (US)Pindyck; Rubinfeld (2001). p. 381.; Steven Morrison in Duetsch (1993), p. 231. **−0.3 (first class) **−0.9 (discount) **−1.5 (for pleasure travelers) * Livestock ** −0.5 to −0.6 ( broiler chickens) * Oil (World) **−0.4 * Car fuel **−0.09 (short run) **−0.31 (long run) **−0.085 to −0.13 (non-linear with price change in the short-run for Saudi Arabia in 2013) * Medicine (US) **−0.31 (medical insurance)Samuelson; Nordhaus (2001). **−0.03 to −0.06 (
pediatric Pediatrics ( also spelled ''paediatrics'' or ''pædiatrics'') is the branch of medicine that involves the medical care of infants, children, adolescents, and young adults. In the United Kingdom, paediatrics covers many of their youth until the ...
visits) * Patents **−0.30 to −0.50de Rassenfosse and van Pottelsberghe (2007, pp. 598; 2012, p. 72) * RicePerloff, J. (2008). **−0.47 (Austria) **−0.8 (Bangladesh) **−0.8 (China) **−0.25 (Japan) **−0.55 (US) * Cinema visits (US) **−0.87 (general) * live performing arts (theater, etc.) ** −0.4 to −0.9 * Transport ** −0.20 (bus travel US) ** −2.8 (Ford compact automobile) ** −0.52 (commuter parking) *Cannabis (US) **−0.655 * Soft drinks **−0.8 to −1.0 (general) **−3.8 (
Coca-Cola Coca-Cola, or Coke, is a carbonated soft drink manufactured by the Coca-Cola Company. Originally marketed as a temperance drink and intended as a patent medicine, it was invented in the late 19th century by John Stith Pemberton in Atlant ...
)Ayers; Collinge (2003). p. 120. **−4.4 ( Mountain Dew) * Steel **−0.2 to −0.3Barnett and Crandall in Duetsch (1993), p. 147 * Telecommunications **−0.405 (mobile) **−0.434 (broadband) *Eggs **−0.1 (US: household only) **−0.35 (Canada) **−0.55 (South Africa) *Golf **−0.3 to −0.7 *University education ** near 0


See also

*
Arc elasticity In mathematics and economics, the arc elasticity is the elasticity of one variable with respect to another between two given points. It is the ratio of the percentage change of one of the variables between the two points to the percentage change of ...
* Cross elasticity of demand *
Income elasticity of demand In economics, the income elasticity of demand is the responsivenesses of the quantity demanded for a good to a change in consumer income. It is measured as the ratio of the percentage change in quantity demanded to the percentage change in incom ...
*
Price elasticity of supply The price elasticity of supply (PES or Es) is a measure used in economics to show the responsiveness, or elasticity, of the quantity supplied of a good or service to a change in its price. The elasticity is represented in numerical form, and ...
* Supply and demand


Notes


References

* * * * * * *
Working paper on RePEc
*

* * * * * * * * * * * * * * * * * * * * * * * * *


External links


A Lesson on Elasticity in Four Parts, Youtube, Jodi BeggsPrice Elasticity Models and OptimizationApprox. PED of Various Products (U.S.)Approx. PED of Various Home-Consumed Foods (U.K.)
{{DEFAULTSORT:Price Elasticity Of Demand Elasticity (economics) Demand Pricing