Giovanni Dosi
   HOME

TheInfoList



OR:

Giovanni Dosi is Professor of Economics and Director of the Institute of Economics at the Scuola Superiore Sant'Anna in
Pisa Pisa ( , or ) is a city and ''comune'' in Tuscany, central Italy, straddling the Arno just before it empties into the Ligurian Sea. It is the capital city of the Province of Pisa. Although Pisa is known worldwide for its leaning tower, the ci ...
. He is the Co-Director of the task forces “Industrial Policy” and “Intellectual Property” at the
Initiative for Policy Dialogue The Initiative for Policy Dialogue (IPD) is a non-profit organization based at Columbia University in the United States. IPD was founded in July 2000 by Joseph E. Stiglitz, with support of the Ford, Rockefeller, McArthur, and Mott Foundations an ...
at Columbia University. Dosi is Continental European Editor of ''Industrial and Corporate Change''. Included in ''ISI Highly Cited Researchers''. His major research areas, where he is author and editor of several works, include economics of innovation and technological change,
industrial organization In economics, industrial organization is a field that builds on the theory of the firm by examining the structure of (and, therefore, the boundaries between) firms and markets. Industrial organization adds real-world complications to the perf ...
and industrial dynamics, theory of the firm and corporate governance, evolutionary theory, economic growth and development. A selection of his works has been published in two volumes: ''Innovation, Organization and Economic Dynamics. Selected Essays'', Cheltenham, Edward Elgar, 2000; and ''Economic Organization, Industrial Dynamics and Development: Selected Essays'', Cheltenham, Edward Elgar, 2012.


Economic analysis

Giovanni Dosi's economic analysis is characterized by the contemporaneous attempt to ''(i)'' identify empirical regularities and ''(ii)'' provide micro-foundations consistent with such regularities. As such, his work is a mix of statistical investigations and theoretical efforts.


Stylized facts

Throughout his work Dosi and his co-authors have identified some stylized facts as being especially relevant for economic analysis,Dosi, G., ''Statistical regularities in the Evolution of Industries. A Guide through some Evidence and Challenges for the Theory'', LEM Working Paper, 17, June, (2005). among others: S.F.1 Over the 19th-20th century technological innovation has proved to be the major contributor to the economic growth of countries, whose growth rates have however displayed an expanding variance. S.F.2 The learning processes that firms undertake to carry out innovations are characterized by trials, errors and unexpected success. S.F.3 Firms are highly heterogeneous in terms of sizes, productivities, and profitabilities. In particular, firm sizes display stationary
skewed distribution In probability theory and statistics, skewness is a measure of the asymmetry of the probability distribution of a real-valued random variable about its mean. The skewness value can be positive, zero, negative, or undefined. For a unimodal ...
s, while productivities and profitabilities display stationary wide supports of their fat tailed distributions. These facts have led Dosi to point out some theoretical implications, which raise contradictions within
Neoclassical economics Neoclassical economics is an approach to economics in which the production, consumption and valuation (pricing) of goods and services are observed as driven by the supply and demand model. According to this line of thought, the value of a good ...
and bear favorable witness to
Evolutionary economics Evolutionary economics is part of mainstream economics as well as a heterodox school of economic thought that is inspired by evolutionary biology. Much like mainstream economics, it stresses complex interdependencies, competition, growth, stru ...
.


Technical change

The role of technological progress as an explanation of contemporary economic growth (S.F.1) has led Dosi to carefully analyze the nature of technology. In particular, he has suggested an interpretation of technical change resting on the concepts of
technological paradigm The concept of technological paradigm is commonly attributed to Giovanni Dosi. The concept is sometimes seen as performing a similar role to the concept of " scientific paradigms", as advanced by Thomas Kuhn. Contributions Giovanni Dosi The role of ...
and
technology trajectory Technology trajectory refers to a single branch in the evolution of a technological design of a product/service, with nodes representing separate designs. With Technology trajectory referring to a single branch we do expect the development of new ...
. In analogy with
Thomas Kuhn Thomas Samuel Kuhn (; July 18, 1922 – June 17, 1996) was an American philosopher of science whose 1962 book '' The Structure of Scientific Revolutions'' was influential in both academic and popular circles, introducing the term ''paradig ...
's definition of a scientific paradigm, Dosi has defined a technological paradigm as the general ''outlook'' on the productive problems faced by firms. As such, a technological paradigm is composed by some sort of ''model'' of the technology at stake (e.g. the model of a microprocessor) and by the specific technological problems posed by such model (e.g. increasing computational capacity, reducing dimensions, etc.). Therefore, technology is identified as a problem-solving activity in which the problems to be solved are selected by the paradigm itself. In this sense, a technological paradigm entails strong prescriptions on the ''direction'' of technological change, that is the direction toward which future technical improvements will converge. Such gradual improvements along the specific lines prescribed by the paradigm are what constitute technological trajectories and progress. Such interpretation of technological change brings Dosi to identify a limited influence of market signals on the ''direction'' of technological change. More precisely, in his view relative prices might affect the direction of technological change only ''within'' the boundaries defined by the nature of the technological paradigm. Such idea can be better understood by analyzing the effect of market signals in their two possible directions: moving "downstream" (i.e. from the technology to the sale of goods) and "upstream" (i.e. from the market environment to the technology). Going "downstream", from the technology to the sale of goods, market signals enter the picture at opposite stages. First, market signals can act ''ex ante'' in the competition among different paradigms: if more paradigms are available, firms would select one or the other according to their expected profitability. But once a paradigm is affirmed, the direction of technological change would be already implied by its technological prescriptions. Second, market signals can act by selecting ''ex post'' those applications of the affirmed paradigm (i.e. the final products) that best fit the market requests. However, at that point their impact on the direction of technical change would be null, since such direction had already been decided by the prescriptions of the affirmed paradigm. Going "upstream", from the market environment to the technology, market signals act to inform the producers of the technology about variations in
relative price A relative price is the price of a commodity such as a good or service in terms of another; i.e., the ratio of two prices. A relative price may be expressed in terms of a ratio between the prices of any two goods or the ratio between the price o ...
s. However, the extent to which technology producers can shift from more expensive to cheaper inputs, or modify technology toward the use of cheaper complement goods is bound by technical constraints. Such constraints emerge because inputs are characterized by low substitutability due to the physical and chemical limits involved in the production process. Consequently, the upstream incentives given by market signals affect only the ''rate'' of use of certain inputs as well as the rate of development of a trajectory but not the ''direction'' of technical change, which is bound by the technical constraints of production.


Uncertainty

The trial and error procedures adopted by firms to improve along a technological trajectory (S.F.2) have taken Dosi to assess the issue of uncertainty. At a general level, trial and error procedures imply that firms might not be able to forecast completely the outcome of a choice they make; in fact, if they could foresee the error, they would presumably avoid it because it is costly. Such a fact is strongly at odds with any assumption of "perfect rationality" or "farsightedness" on the side of economic agents, which is a foundational element of the Neoclassical approach. Dosi has analyzed this issue by assessing the ways in which economic agents perceive and deal with choices that have an uncertain outcome. In analogy with Herbert A. Simon's distinction about rationality, he has proposed the distinction between substantive uncertainty and procedural uncertainty.Dosi, G. and Egidi, M., ''Substantive and procedural Uncertainty. An exploration of economic behavior in changing environments'', Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 1(2):145-168, (1991). In his view, "the former is related to some lack of information about environmental events, while the latter concerns the competence gap in problem-solving". Nonetheless, both of them generate "limitations on the computational and cognitive capabilities of the agents to pursue unambiguously their objectives". Crucially, though, the fact that such types of uncertainties limit the computational rationality of agents leads them precisely to develop routines and decision rules that are the likely explanation of their heterogeneous behaviors. Moreover, even though such routines and decision rules are not optimally determined, they might well prove more "intelligent" than "optimal" decisions especially when applied to turbulent selection landscapes.


Heterogeneity

The fact that firms appear to be consistently heterogeneous (S.F.3) has brought Dosi to criticize the Neoclassical prediction that firms in an industry converge toward some kind of "optimal" or "representative" characteristic. For such argument to be valid, the characteristics of firms would need to evolve in time toward a
normal distribution In statistics, a normal distribution or Gaussian distribution is a type of continuous probability distribution for a real-valued random variable. The general form of its probability density function is : f(x) = \frac e^ The parameter \mu ...
, possibly showing some shrinking of the support. Notably, this theoretical implication poses an unresolved challenge to the arguments put forward by
Milton Friedman Milton Friedman (; July 31, 1912 – November 16, 2006) was an American economist and statistician who received the 1976 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences for his research on consumption analysis, monetary history and theory and the ...
in his essay ''The Methodology of Positive Economics''. In such work Friedman asserted that maximizing behavior was a reasonable working approximation to describe the choices of economic agents: in fact, even if not all economic agents actually maximize (for example because some make mistakes) only the "fittest" ones will be selected by the market. Therefore, those agents that actually maximize would be the only "survivors" to market selection, and hence they would gather very closely around the single optimal behavior. In other words, the tails of the distribution will tend to disappear as market selects the best "genes", which would turn out to be both "optimal" (in terms of fit to the market selection) and "representative" (since it would be the only surviving type). However, the empirical findings that constitute S.F.3 prove the exact opposite of Friedman's prediction: very different "genes" survive to the market. As a consequence, a realistic representation of economic behavior should rather allow for firm-specificities, which would explain the heterogeneity found in the data: a point that was clearly made by Richard Nelson and Sidney Winter in their book ''An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change''.Nelson, R.R. and Winter S.G., ''An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change'', Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA, (1982). pp.72-136.


References

{{DEFAULTSORT:Dosi, Giovanni Innovation economists Italian economists Economics educators Academics of the University of Manchester Academics of the University of Sussex Science and Technology Policy Research alumni Sant'Anna School of Advanced Studies faculty Living people 1953 births