HOME

TheInfoList



OR:

In economics, lexicographic preferences or lexicographic orderings describe comparative preferences where an
agent Agent may refer to: Espionage, investigation, and law *, spies or intelligence officers * Law of agency, laws involving a person authorized to act on behalf of another ** Agent of record, a person with a contractual agreement with an insuranc ...
prefers any amount of one good (X) to any amount of another (Y). Specifically, if offered several bundles of goods, the agent will choose the bundle that offers the most X, no matter how much Y there is. Only when there is a tie between bundles with regard to the number of units of X will the agent start comparing the number of units of Y across bundles. Lexicographic preferences extend
utility theory As a topic of economics, utility is used to model worth or value. Its usage has evolved significantly over time. The term was introduced initially as a measure of pleasure or happiness as part of the theory of utilitarianism by moral philosoph ...
analogously to the way that nonstandard infinitesimals extend the real numbers. With lexicographic preferences, the utility of certain goods is infinitesimal in comparison to others.


Etymology

''
Lexicography Lexicography is the study of lexicons, and is divided into two separate academic disciplines. It is the art of compiling dictionaries. * Practical lexicography is the art or craft of compiling, writing and editing dictionaries. * Theoretica ...
'' refers to the compilation of dictionaries, and is meant to invoke the fact that a dictionary is organized alphabetically: with infinite attention to the first letter of each word, and only in the event of ties with attention to the second letter of each word, etc.


Example

As an example, if for a given bundle (X;Y;Z) an agent orders his preferences according to the rule X>>Y>>Z, then the bundles would be ordered, from most to least preferred: # 5;3;3 # 5;1;6 # 3;5;3 *Even though the first option contains fewer total goods than the second option, it is preferred because it has more Y. Note that the number of X's is the same, and so the agent is comparing Y's. *Even though the third option has the same total goods as the first option, the first option is still preferred because it has more X. *Even though the third option has far more Y than the second option, the second option is still preferred because it has more X. A distinctive feature of such lexicographic preferences is that a multivariate real
domain Domain may refer to: Mathematics *Domain of a function, the set of input values for which the (total) function is defined ** Domain of definition of a partial function ** Natural domain of a partial function ** Domain of holomorphy of a function * ...
of an agent's preferences does not map into a real-valued
range Range may refer to: Geography * Range (geographic), a chain of hills or mountains; a somewhat linear, complex mountainous or hilly area (cordillera, sierra) ** Mountain range, a group of mountains bordered by lowlands * Range, a term used to i ...
. That is, there is no real-valued representation of a
utility function As a topic of economics, utility is used to model worth or value. Its usage has evolved significantly over time. The term was introduced initially as a measure of pleasure or happiness as part of the theory of utilitarianism by moral philosophe ...
. Amartya K. Sen, 1970
984 Year 984 ( CMLXXXIV) was a leap year starting on Tuesday (link will display the full calendar) of the Julian calendar. Events By place Europe * Spring – German boy-king Otto III (4-years old) is seized by the deposed Henry II ( ...
''Collective Choice and Social Welfare'', ch. 3, "Collective Rationality," pp. 34-35
Description.
In terms of real valued utility, one would say that the utility of Y and Z is infinitesimal compared with X, and the utility of Z is
infinitesimal In mathematics, an infinitesimal number is a quantity that is closer to zero than any standard real number, but that is not zero. The word ''infinitesimal'' comes from a 17th-century Modern Latin coinage ''infinitesimus'', which originally ref ...
compared to Y.


Implications

If all agents have the same lexicographic preferences, then
general equilibrium In economics, general equilibrium theory attempts to explain the behavior of supply, demand, and prices in a whole economy with several or many interacting markets, by seeking to prove that the interaction of demand and supply will result in an ov ...
cannot exist because agents won't sell to each other (as long as
price A price is the (usually not negative) quantity of payment or compensation given by one party to another in return for goods or services. In some situations, the price of production has a different name. If the product is a "good" in the c ...
of the less preferred is more than
zero 0 (zero) is a number representing an empty quantity. In place-value notation such as the Hindu–Arabic numeral system, 0 also serves as a placeholder numerical digit, which works by multiplying digits to the left of 0 by the radix, usuall ...
). But if the price of the less wanted is zero, then all agents want an infinite amount of the good. Equilibrium cannot be attained with standard prices. The utilities are infinitesimal, but the prices are not. Allowing infinitesimal prices resolves this. Lexicographic preferences can still exist with general equilibrium. For example, *Different people have different bundles of lexicographic preferences such that different individuals value items in different orders. *Some, but not all people have lexicographic preferences. *Lexicographic preferences extend only to a certain quantity of the good. The nonstandard equilibrium prices for exchange can be determined for lexicographic order using standard equilibrium methods, except using nonstandard reals as the range of both utilities and prices. All the theorems regarding existence of prices and equilibria extend to the case of nonstandard utilities, since the nonstandard reals form a conservative extension, meaning that any theorem which is true for reals can be extended to the nonstandard reals and remains true. Lexicographic preferences are the classical example of rational preferences that are not representable by a
utility function As a topic of economics, utility is used to model worth or value. Its usage has evolved significantly over time. The term was introduced initially as a measure of pleasure or happiness as part of the theory of utilitarianism by moral philosophe ...
over the standard reals. If there were such a function ''U'' then, e.g. for 2 goods, the intervals 'U''(''x'',0),''U''(''x'',1)would have a non-zero width and be disjoint for all ''x'', which is not possible for an uncountable set of x-values. If there are a finite number of goods and amounts can only be rational numbers, utility functions do exist, simply by taking 1/N to be the size of the infinitesimal, where N is sufficiently large, to approximate nonstandard numbers. The relation is not continuous because for a decreasing
convergent sequence As the positive integer n becomes larger and larger, the value n\cdot \sin\left(\tfrac1\right) becomes arbitrarily close to 1. We say that "the limit of the sequence n\cdot \sin\left(\tfrac1\right) equals 1." In mathematics, the limi ...
x_n \rightarrow 0 we have (x_n,0)>(0,1), while the limit (0,0) is smaller than (0,1).


Notes

{{Reflist, 1


External links


Lexicographic preference relation cannot be represented by a utility function
In Economics.SE
Recognizing linear orders embeddable in R2 ordered lexicographically
In Math.SE.
Lexicographic Multi-Objective Linear Programming using Grossone Methodology: Theory and Algorithm
In Appl. Math. and Computation Consumer theory Lexicography Utility function types de:Präferenzrelation#Lexikographische Präferenzordnung