HOME

TheInfoList



OR:

The expectations hypothesis of the
term structure of interest rates In finance, the yield curve is a graph which depicts how the yields on debt instruments - such as bonds - vary as a function of their years remaining to maturity. Typically, the graph's horizontal or x-axis is a time line of months or y ...
(whose graphical representation is known as the
yield curve In finance, the yield curve is a graph which depicts how the Yield to maturity, yields on debt instruments - such as bonds - vary as a function of their years remaining to Maturity (finance), maturity. Typically, the graph's horizontal or ...
) is the proposition that the long-term rate is determined purely by current and future expected short-term rates, in such a way that the expected final value of wealth from investing in a sequence of short-term bonds equals the final value of wealth from investing in long-term bonds. This hypothesis assumes that the various maturities are perfect substitutes and suggests that the shape of the
yield curve In finance, the yield curve is a graph which depicts how the Yield to maturity, yields on debt instruments - such as bonds - vary as a function of their years remaining to Maturity (finance), maturity. Typically, the graph's horizontal or ...
depends on market participants' expectations of future interest rates. These expected rates, along with an assumption that arbitrage opportunities will be minimal, is enough information to construct a complete yield curve. For example, if investors have an expectation of what 1-year interest rates will be next year, the 2-year interest rate can be calculated as the compounding of this year's interest rate by next year's interest rate. More generally, returns (1 + yield) on a long-term instrument are equal to the geometric mean of the returns on a series of short-term instruments, as given by :(1 + i_)^n=(1 + i_^)(1 + i_^) \cdots (1 + i_^), where ''lt'' and ''st'' respectively refer to long-term and short-term bonds, and where interest rates ''i'' for future years are expected values. This theory is consistent with the observation that yields usually move together. However, it fails to explain the persistence in the non-horizontal shape of the yield curve.


Definition

The expectation hypothesis states that the current price of an asset is equal to the sum of expected discounted future dividends conditional on the information known now. Mathematically if there are discrete dividend payments d_t at times t = 1,2,... and with
risk-free rate The risk-free rate of return, usually shortened to the risk-free rate, is the rate of return of a hypothetical investment with scheduled payments over a fixed period of time that is assumed to meet all payment obligations. Since the risk-free ra ...
r then the price at time t is given by : P_t = \sum_^ \left(\frac\right)^ \mathbb _ \mid \mathcal_t/math> where \mathcal_t is a
filtration Filtration is a physical separation process that separates solid matter and fluid from a mixture using a ''filter medium'' that has a complex structure through which only the fluid can pass. Solid particles that cannot pass through the filter m ...
which defines the market at time t. In particular, the price of a
coupon bond In finance, a coupon is the interest payment received by a bondholder from the date of issuance until the date of maturity of a bond. Coupons are normally described in terms of the "coupon rate", which is calculated by adding the sum of coupons ...
, with coupons given by m_t at time t, is given by :P_t = \sum_^ m_n B(t,n) = \frac + \frac \mathbb _ \mid \mathcal_t/math> where r(t,T) is the short-term interest rate from time t to time T and B(t,T) is the value of a
zero-coupon bond A zero coupon bond (also discount bond or deep discount bond) is a bond in which the face value is repaid at the time of maturity. Unlike regular bonds, it does not make periodic interest payments or have so-called coupons, hence the term zer ...
at time t and maturity T with payout of 1 at maturity. Explicitly, the price of a zero-coupon bond is given by : B(t,T) = \mathbb 1 + r(t,t+1))^ \cdots (1 + r(T-1,T))^ \mid \mathcal_t= \frac \mathbb (t+1,T) \mid \mathcal_t/math>.


Shortcomings

The expectation hypothesis neglects the risks inherent in investing in bonds (because forward rates are not perfect predictors of future rates). In particular this can be broken down into two categories: #
Interest rate risk In finance and economics, interest is payment from a borrower or deposit-taking financial institution to a lender or depositor of an amount above repayment of the principal sum (that is, the amount borrowed), at a particular rate. It is distin ...
# Reinvestment rate risk It has been found that the expectation hypothesis has been tested and rejected using a wide variety of interest rates, over a variety of time periods and
monetary policy Monetary policy is the policy adopted by the monetary authority of a nation to control either the interest rate payable for very short-term borrowing (borrowing by banks from each other to meet their short-term needs) or the money supply, often ...
regimes. This analysis is supported in a study conducted by Sarno, Sarno, L.; Thornton, D.; Valente, G. (2007). "The Empirical Failure of the Expectations Hypothesis of the Term Structure of Bond Yields". ''Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis'' 42 (1): 81–100. doi:10.1017/S0022109000002192. where it is concluded that while conventional bivariate procedure provides mixed results, the more powerful testing procedures, for example expanded
vector autoregression Vector autoregression (VAR) is a statistical model used to capture the relationship between multiple quantities as they change over time. VAR is a type of stochastic process model. VAR models generalize the single-variable (univariate) autoregres ...
test, suggest rejection of the expectation hypothesis throughout the maturity spectrum examined. A common reason given for the failure of the expectation hypothesis is that the risk premium is not constant as the expectation hypothesis requires, but is time-varying. However, research by Guidolin and Thornton (2008) suggest otherwise. It is postulated that the expectation hypothesis fails because short-term interest rates are not predictable to any significant degree. While traditional term structure tests mostly indicate that expected future interest rates are ex post inefficient forecasts, Froot (1989) has an alternative take on it. At short maturities, the expectation hypothesis fails. At long maturities, however, changes in the yield curve reflect changes in expected future rates one-for-one.


References

{{Reflist Economics curves Finance theories Fixed income