Wealth Maximization
   HOME

TheInfoList



OR:

Wealth maximization is a normative principle in
welfare economics Welfare economics is a field of economics that applies microeconomic techniques to evaluate the overall well-being (welfare) of a society. The principles of welfare economics are often used to inform public economics, which focuses on the ...
that seeks to maximize the total “economic surplus” in society by summing individuals’ willingness to pay for desired goods, services, or states of affairs. Although it originated in theoretical economics—most notably through the work on
Kaldor–Hicks efficiency A Kaldor–Hicks improvement, named for Nicholas Kaldor and John Hicks, is an economic re-allocation of resources among people that captures some of the intuitive appeal of a Pareto improvement, but has less stringent criteria and is hence appl ...
—it later became a central concept in
law and economics Law and economics, or economic analysis of law, is the application of microeconomic theory to the analysis of law. The field emerged in the United States during the early 1960s, primarily from the work of scholars from the Chicago school of econ ...
, particularly under the influence of
Richard Posner Richard Allen Posner (; born January 11, 1939) is an American legal scholar and retired United States circuit judge who served on the U.S. Court of Appeals for the Seventh Circuit from 1981 to 2017. A senior lecturer at the University of Chicag ...
. Proponents argue that many legal doctrines appear to promote efficient resource allocation when measured by this willingness-to-pay standard, while critics contend it can neglect distributive fairness, rights, or moral values that do not reduce neatly to monetary terms.


Development


Welfare Economics

Wealth maximization is closely linked to the evolution of welfare economics in the early and mid-20th century.
Vilfredo Pareto Vilfredo Federico Damaso Pareto (; ; born Wilfried Fritz Pareto; 15 July 1848 – 19 August 1923) was an Italian polymath, whose areas of interest included sociology, civil engineering, economics, political science, and philosophy. He made severa ...
introduced the idea of
Pareto efficiency In welfare economics, a Pareto improvement formalizes the idea of an outcome being "better in every possible way". A change is called a Pareto improvement if it leaves at least one person in society better off without leaving anyone else worse ...
, under which a policy change is “better” only if at least one person is made better off without making anyone else worse off. In practice, few real-world policies meet that standard, prompting scholars such as Nicholas Kaldor and John Hicks to propose a more flexible “compensation criterion” in the late 1930s. Under what later became known as
Kaldor–Hicks efficiency A Kaldor–Hicks improvement, named for Nicholas Kaldor and John Hicks, is an economic re-allocation of resources among people that captures some of the intuitive appeal of a Pareto improvement, but has less stringent criteria and is hence appl ...
, a policy is considered efficient if the “winners” from the policy could in theory compensate the “losers” and still come out ahead, even if actual compensation does not occur. These ideas laid the groundwork for “wealth maximization” as a normative principle: maximize total willingness-to-pay across society, thereby favoring changes that generate a net increase in economic surplus. While this approach allows trade-offs in which some parties lose, it justifies them by positing that society’s overall resources increase enough that losers ''could'' be compensated through separate policy mechanisms (e.g., taxes and transfers).


Key Concepts and Clarifications

Under
Pareto efficiency In welfare economics, a Pareto improvement formalizes the idea of an outcome being "better in every possible way". A change is called a Pareto improvement if it leaves at least one person in society better off without leaving anyone else worse ...
, any change that makes even one individual worse off is disallowed, unless compensated. Because most large-scale reforms will harm at least some parties, Pareto improvements are rare. By contrast, under
Kaldor–Hicks efficiency A Kaldor–Hicks improvement, named for Nicholas Kaldor and John Hicks, is an economic re-allocation of resources among people that captures some of the intuitive appeal of a Pareto improvement, but has less stringent criteria and is hence appl ...
—the foundation of wealth maximization—the focus is on ''net'' gains. A policy is deemed beneficial if it creates enough surplus so that losers ''could'' be indemnified by winners, even if such compensation does not literally occur. A frequent misunderstanding is that wealth maximization aims to increase the quantity of money itself. However, “wealth” here represents the total value that individuals place on outcomes. Hence, money is simply ''a tool for measuring preference intensity''. In this framework, if someone pays $50 for a good, that suggests it is worth at least $50 to them relative to other uses of those funds. Proponents note that a monetary measure is relatively transparent, observable, widely understood, and operational in markets. However, critics contend that when individuals have very different incomes, willingness-to-pay may not accurately capture how strongly each party values a good (the so-called “affluence effect”).


Centrality in Law and Economics

Law and economics Law and economics, or economic analysis of law, is the application of microeconomic theory to the analysis of law. The field emerged in the United States during the early 1960s, primarily from the work of scholars from the Chicago school of econ ...
is an intellectual movement that applies economic tools to analyze legal rules, institutions, and policies. It gained prominence in the United States from the 1970s onward, advocating that many legal doctrines—torts, contracts, property, and so forth—can be better understood by examining how they affect incentives and resource allocation. A major catalyst was
Richard Posner Richard Allen Posner (; born January 11, 1939) is an American legal scholar and retired United States circuit judge who served on the U.S. Court of Appeals for the Seventh Circuit from 1981 to 2017. A senior lecturer at the University of Chicag ...
’s ''Economic Analysis of Law'' (1973), which presented the idea that legal rules often (consciously or not) promote socially efficient outcomes aligned with wealth maximization. Courts and policymakers subsequently began invoking efficiency arguments, and wealth maximization became a key concept for evaluating whether a given legal rule increases total surplus. By the 1980s, law and economics had become a dominant approach in U.S. legal scholarship, shaping everything from judicial reasoning to legislative impact assessments.


Critiques


Distribution and justice

A primary objection is that wealth maximization can ignore the distribution of resources. If a wealthy party’s willingness to pay for some benefit greatly exceeds a poorer party’s, the result may be deemed “efficient” even though it exacerbates inequality. Philosophers such as
Ronald Dworkin Ronald Myles Dworkin (; December 11, 1931 – February 14, 2013) was an American legal philosopher, jurist, and scholar of United States constitutional law. At the time of his death, he was Frank Henry Sommer Professor of Law and Philosophy at ...
and G.A. Cohen argue that legal institutions cannot be judged solely by efficiency if they systematically favor the affluent. Proponents respond that fairness goals are better addressed through tax-and-transfer schemes rather than tinkering with core legal doctrines, thus preserving economic efficiency in the legal system while allowing society to correct undesirable inequalities elsewhere.


Rights-based objections

Another critique is that fundamental rights may be overridden if efficiency gains are large enough. For instance, if suppressing speech yielded a significant net increase in economic surplus, a strict wealth-maximization approach might endorse it. Defenders argue that clear and stable rights often contribute to long-term prosperity, reducing uncertainty and facilitating exchanges that increase wealth, and that some rights may need to be treated as “off limits” to routine cost-benefit analysis.


Moral value and incommensurability

Wealth maximization has also been challenged by theorists who emphasize non-monetary values such as dignity, autonomy, or democratic participation.
Martha Nussbaum Martha Nussbaum (; Craven; born May 6, 1947) is an American philosopher and the current Ernst Freund Distinguished Service Professor of Law and Ethics at the University of Chicago, where she is jointly appointed in the law school and the philos ...
’s capabilities approach, for example, stresses the importance of human functioning and “capabilities” that can be undervalued when everything is measured by willingness to pay. Proponents maintain that legal systems almost universally employ monetary mechanisms (e.g., damages, fines) to enforce rights and obligations, making a financial metric an unavoidable common denominator—albeit one that should be supplemented by ethical and institutional safeguards.


Defenses and Justifications


Posner's Defense of Wealth Maximization

In “Wealth Maximization Revisited,” Posner addressed criticisms that wealth maximization was too narrow or overlooked rights. He argued that, in the long run, social welfare and moral intuitions often align with rules that maximize overall resources. By encouraging productivity and exchange, these rules can provide the material basis for achieving various social and individual goals.


“Fairness versus Welfare”

Louis Kaplow Louis Kaplow (born June 17, 1956) is an American legal scholar and economist. He is the Finn M. W. Caspersen and Household International Professor of Law and Economics at Harvard Law School. He has made contributions to antitrust law, competition ...
and
Steven Shavell Steven Shavell is an economist who is currently Samuel R. Rosenthal Professor of Law and Economics at Harvard Law School. Shavell is the founder and director of the School's John M. Olin Center for Law, Economics, and Business. Biography Steve ...
further developed this efficiency-based perspective in ''Fairness versus Welfare'', contending that direct pursuit of economic efficiency need not conflict with fairness—provided that society handles redistribution through income tax or other fiscal tools, rather than attempting to embed equity principles in every legal rule. They argue that structuring the legal system primarily around efficiency fosters clarity, predictability, and wealth creation, while separate fiscal programs can address the inequities that arise from market outcomes. By segregating these functions, Kaplow and Shavell maintain, policymakers can more systematically counteract regressive effects without compromising the incentive structures that promote overall wealth. In their view, conflating equity goals with legal doctrines can lead to muddled policies and unintended consequences. For example, a tort rule calibrated to redistribute wealth between parties might weaken deterrence or distort settlement incentives. Similarly, a property rule tweaked for fairness could reduce the incentives for private investment. Thus, Kaplow and Shavell claim that mixing efficiency and equity in the same doctrinal sphere often undermines both. Instead, they recommend using legal rules to maximize societal surplus and then relying on well-crafted taxes and transfers to address distributive concerns.


Social Contract Foundations

Daniel Pi and Francesco Parisi argue that wealth maximization can be normatively grounded in liberal
social contract In moral and political philosophy, the social contract is an idea, theory, or model that usually, although not always, concerns the legitimacy of the authority of the state over the individual. Conceptualized in the Age of Enlightenment, it ...
theory. They maintain that by pushing total economic surplus to its highest feasible level, a wealth-maximizing regime creates the broadest “bargaining space,” affording those who benefit the most the greatest ability to compensate or placate potential dissenters—individuals who might otherwise refuse assent or disrupt the social contract. This dynamic, Pi and Parisi maintain, fosters broad assent in a
Hobbesian Thomas Hobbes ( ; 5 April 1588 – 4 December 1679) was an English philosopher, best known for his 1651 book ''Leviathan'', in which he expounds an influential formulation of social contract theory. He is considered to be one of the founders ...
sense and, moreover, corresponds to what a risk-neutral individual would choose behind a Rawlsian “veil of ignorance.” Pi and Parisi contend that wealth maximization should not be viewed merely as a pragmatic stand-in for utilitarianism. Rather, they present it as an autonomous theory with a stronger normative basis in liberal political philosophy, offering deeper justifications than classical utility-based approaches.


References

Cooter, R., & Ulen, T. (2011). ''Law and Economics'' (6th ed.). Pearson. Ash, E., Chen, D.L., & Naidu, S. (2022). "Ideas Have Consequences: The Impact of Law and Economics on American Justice." NBER Working Paper No. 29788. Posner, R.A. (1973). ''Economic Analysis of Law.'' Boston: Little, Brown. Posner, R.A. (1985). "Wealth Maximization Revisited." ''Notre Dame Journal of Law, Ethics & Public Policy'' 2(1): 85–105. Kaplow, L. & Shavell, S. (2002). ''Fairness versus Welfare.'' Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Pi, D., & Parisi, F. (2023). "Wealth Maximization Redux: A Defense of Posner’s Economic Approach to Law." ''History of Economic Ideas'' 31: 101–136. Kaplow, L. & Shavell, S. (1994). "Why the Legal System Is Less Efficient than the Income Tax in Redistributing Income." ''Journal of Legal Studies'' 23(2): 667–681. Hicks, J. (1939). "The Foundations of Welfare Economics." ''The Economic Journal'' 49(196): 696–712. Kaldor, N. (1939). "Welfare Propositions in Economics and Interpersonal Comparisons of Utility." ''The Economic Journal'' 49(195): 549–552. Scitovsky, T. (1941). "A Note on Welfare Propositions in Economics." ''Review of Economic Studies'' 9(1): 77–88. Dworkin, R. (1980). "Is Wealth a Value?" ''Journal of Legal Studies'' 9(2): 191–226. Cohen, G.A. (2000). "If You’re an Egalitarian, How Come You’re So Rich?" ''The Journal of Ethics'' 4(1): 1–26. Bowles, S. & Gintis, H. (2011). ''A Cooperative Species: Human Reciprocity and Its Evolution.'' Princeton: Princeton University Press. Nussbaum, M. (2000). ''Women and Human Development: The Capabilities Approach.'' Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Law and economics Welfare economics