Warm-glow giving is an economic theory describing the emotional reward of giving to others. According to the original warm-glow model developed by
James Andreoni
James Andreoni (born 1959 in Beloit, Wisconsin) is a professor in the Economics Department of the University of California, San Diego where he directs the EconLab. His research focuses on behavioral economics, experimental economics, and public eco ...
(1989, 1990),
people experience a sense of joy and satisfaction for "doing their part" to help others. This satisfaction - or "''warm glow"'' - represents the selfish pleasure derived from "doing good", regardless of the actual impact of one's generosity. Within the warm-glow framework, people may be "impurely altruistic", meaning they simultaneously maintain both altruistic and egoistic (selfish) motivations for giving. This may be partially due to the fact that "warm glow" sometimes gives people credit for the contributions they make, such as a plaque with their name or a system where they can make donations publicly so other people know the "good" they are doing for the community.
Whereas "pure altruists" (sometimes referred to as "perfect altruists") are motivated solely by the desire to provide for a recipient, impure altruists are also motivated by the joy of giving (warm glow).
Importantly, warm glow is distinctly non-pecuniary,
meaning it arises independent of the possibility of financial reward. Therefore, the warm glow phenomenon is distinct from
reciprocal altruism
In evolutionary biology, reciprocal altruism is a behaviour whereby an organism acts in a manner that temporarily reduces its fitness while increasing another organism's fitness, with the expectation that the other organism will act in a similar m ...
, which may imply a direct financial incentive.
Warm-glow giving is a useful economic framework to consider public good provision, collective action problems, charitable giving, and gifting behavior. The existence of a warm glow helps explain the absence of complete crowding-out of private giving by public grants, as predicted by classical economic models under the neutrality hypothesis.
Beyond economics, warm glow has been applied to sociology, political science,
environmental policy,
healthcare,
and business.
Conceptually, warm-glow giving is related to the notion of a "helper's high"
and appears to be resilient across cultures.
Background in moral philosophy
Warm glow is built upon the idea of impure altruism: the blend of both altruistic and egoistic desires to help others.
Philosophers have debated this idea since the time of the ancient Greeks.
In the
Socratic ''dialogues'', motivation may be traced to an egoistic concern for one's own welfare, thus denying the plausibility of pure altruism.
Similarly,
Plato
Plato ( ; Greek language, Greek: , ; born BC, died 348/347 BC) was an ancient Greek philosopher of the Classical Greece, Classical period who is considered a foundational thinker in Western philosophy and an innovator of the writte ...
's organization of motivations as responses to hunger-based desires highlights the foundational importance of egoism in all social interactions.
However, in
Nicomachean Ethics
The ''Nicomachean Ethics'' (; , ) is Aristotle's best-known work on ethics: the science of the good for human life, that which is the goal or end at which all our actions aim. () It consists of ten sections, referred to as books, and is closely ...
and
Eudemian Ethics
The ''Eudemian Ethics'' (; or ''De moribus ad Eudemum'') is a work of philosophy by Aristotle. Its primary focus is on ethics, making it one of the primary sources available for study of Aristotelian ethics. It is named for Eudemus of Rhodes, ...
, Aristotle considers both the possibility and necessity of altruism to fulfill high-order eudaimonic goals,
thus setting the stage for an ongoing philosophical debate.
Hobbes
Thomas Hobbes ( ; 5 April 1588 – 4 December 1679) was an English philosopher, best known for his 1651 book ''Leviathan'', in which he expounds an influential formulation of social contract theory. He is considered to be one of the founders ...
,
Kant
Immanuel Kant (born Emanuel Kant; 22 April 1724 – 12 February 1804) was a German philosopher and one of the central Enlightenment thinkers. Born in Königsberg, Kant's comprehensive and systematic works in epistemology, metaphysics, et ...
,
Nietzsche
Friedrich Wilhelm Nietzsche (15 October 1844 – 25 August 1900) was a German philosopher. He began his career as a classical philologist, turning to philosophy early in his academic career. In 1869, aged 24, Nietzsche became the youngest pro ...
,
Bentham,
J.S. Mill argued against the possibility of pure altruism
and advanced the doctrine of
psychological egoism
Psychological egoism is the view that humans are always motivated by self-interest and selfishness, even in what seem to be acts of altruism. It claims that, when people choose to help others, they do so ultimately because of the personal benefit ...
, while others (
Butler
A butler is a person who works in a house serving and is a domestic worker in a large household. In great houses, the household is sometimes divided into departments, with the butler in charge of the dining room, wine cellar, and pantries, pantr ...
,
Hume,
Rousseau
Jean-Jacques Rousseau (, ; ; 28 June 1712 – 2 July 1778) was a Genevan philosopher ('' philosophe''), writer, and composer. His political philosophy influenced the progress of the Age of Enlightenment throughout Europe, as well as aspects ...
,
Adam Smith
Adam Smith (baptised 1723 – 17 July 1790) was a Scottish economist and philosopher who was a pioneer in the field of political economy and key figure during the Scottish Enlightenment. Seen by some as the "father of economics"——— or ...
,
Nagel) argued for the existence of altruistic motives.
Conceptually, the warm-glow model represents a stylized compromise between these two perspectives, allowing for individuals to be purely altruistic, purely egoistic, or impurely altruistic.
Warm glow is at least tangentially related to the topic of
free will
Free will is generally understood as the capacity or ability of people to (a) choice, choose between different possible courses of Action (philosophy), action, (b) exercise control over their actions in a way that is necessary for moral respon ...
, as people should only reap the psychological reward of helping if they freely choose to do so.
Background in economics
Departure from Classical theory
The normative theory of
Ricardian equivalence
The Ricardian equivalence proposition (also known as the Ricardo–de Viti–Barro equivalence theorem) is an economic hypothesis holding that consumers are forward-looking and so internalize the government's budget constraint when making their co ...
suggests private spending should be unresponsive to
fiscal policy
In economics and political science, fiscal policy is the use of government revenue collection ( taxes or tax cuts) and expenditure to influence a country's economy. The use of government revenue expenditures to influence macroeconomic variab ...
because forward-looking individuals smooth their consumption, consistent with Modigliani's
life-cycle hypothesis In economics, the life-cycle hypothesis (LCH) is a model that strives to explain the consumption patterns of individuals.
Theory and evidence
Elderly dissaving is also influenced by the present factors that materially prevent them from the possibi ...
. Applied to the provision of charities or
public good
In economics, a public good (also referred to as a social good or collective good)Oakland, W. H. (1987). Theory of public goods. In Handbook of public economics (Vol. 2, pp. 485–535). Elsevier. is a commodity, product or service that is bo ...
s, Ricardian equivalence and the classical assumption of pure altruism together support the neutrality hypothesis,
implying perfect substitutability between private and public contributions. The neutrality hypothesis assumes rational economic agents are indifferent to whether a cause is funded by the private or public sector; only the level of funding is relevant. A consequence of neutrality under perfect altruism is that government grants should completely crowd-out private donations. That is, a dollar given by the government takes the place of a dollar that would have been given by a private citizen.
To illustrate, economic agents operating under the neutrality hypothesis would give to a cause until complete provision, beyond which they would contribute nothing.
This is consistent with Andreoni's conceptualization of "pure altruism"; however, it is inconsistent with impure altruism or pure egoism.
Thus, warm glow and the failure to act as purely altruistic present fundamental challenges to the neutrality hypothesis and Ricardian equivalence.
In economics, violations to the neutrality hypothesis pose serious concerns for macroeconomic policies involving taxation and redistribution; and microeconomic theories for
collective action
Collective action refers to action taken together Advocacy group, by a group of people whose goal is to enhance their condition and achieve a common objective. It is a term that has formulations and theories in many areas of the social sciences ...
and
public good provision.
Several of Andreoni's contemporaries simultaneously provided evidence against neutrality-driven crowding-out effects, including Kingma (1989) and Khanna et al. (1995). Taken together, these findings offered a strong rebuke of the assumption that public grants crowd-out private donations to public goods.
Original model
Andreoni's economic model of impure altruism considers a simplistic world with only two goods: a
private good
Private or privates may refer to:
Music
* "In Private", by Dusty Springfield from the 1990 album ''Reputation''
* Private (band), a Denmark-based band
* "Private" (Ryōko Hirosue song), from the 1999 album ''Private'', written and also recorded ...
and a
public good
In economics, a public good (also referred to as a social good or collective good)Oakland, W. H. (1987). Theory of public goods. In Handbook of public economics (Vol. 2, pp. 485–535). Elsevier. is a commodity, product or service that is bo ...
. A given individual, endowed with wealth
faces the
budget constraint
In economics, a budget constraint represents all the combinations of goods and services that a consumer may purchase given current prices within their given income. Consumer theory uses the concepts of a budget constraint and a preference map ...
:
where
represents consumption of a private good, and
represents the contribution to the public good. To the extent that
positively contributes to
utility
In economics, utility is a measure of a certain person's satisfaction from a certain state of the world. Over time, the term has been used with at least two meanings.
* In a normative context, utility refers to a goal or objective that we wish ...
, it may be interpreted as the degree of warm glow.
It follows that the total provision of the public good, G, is simply:
and the total contributions to the public good from all other individuals is denoted as:
Thus, the public good is the sum of the
person's contribution
along with the total contributions of all other individuals
(1)
where
All individuals in this naïve economy face the same
utility function
In economics, utility is a measure of a certain person's satisfaction from a certain state of the world. Over time, the term has been used with at least two meanings.
* In a Normative economics, normative context, utility refers to a goal or ob ...
s, given by:
(2)
where the utility functions represent the utility for private, egoistic consumption
the utility derived from the public good
and the warm-glow utility of the contribution towards the public good
An altruist should derive no additional utility from the act of giving:
whereas a pure egoist derives pleasure only from the warm glow of giving, without care for the public good itself, hence
From the budget constraint and utility function, one can derive the utility maximization function,
which is the original utility function (2) transformed using the definition of the public good (1).
This utility maximization function serves as the foundation for warm-glow model development
Implications
Assuming a strategy of utility maximization, the model of warm glow offers many important economic predictions. Specifically, it presents three contrarian insights to those of classical economics under Ricardian equivalence.
First, warm-glow theory predicts that income transfers will increase net giving only when income is transferred to more altruistic individuals. Second, it suggests that the provision of a public good is dependent upon the distribution of income within a population. Third, it suggests that public fund of public goods through lump-sum taxes will be more effective than relying upon altruism in the private sector.
Individually and collectively, these propositions are in stark contrast to the
laissez-faire
''Laissez-faire'' ( , from , ) is a type of economic system in which transactions between private groups of people are free from any form of economic interventionism (such as subsidies or regulations). As a system of thought, ''laissez-faire'' ...
doctrine of Ricardian economics.
Following this original model, warm glow has conceptually evolved with new applications across disciplines to explain and encourage
prosocial behavior
Prosocial behavior is a social behavior that "benefit other people or society as a whole", "such as helping, sharing, donating, co-operating, and volunteering". The person may or may not intend to benefit others; the behavior's prosocial benef ...
.
Background in psychology
Many of the advances in warm glow research stem not from economics, but from psychology. In particular, research on motivations and affect have played a key role in defining and operationalizing warm glow for broad application.
A motivational perspective
''"...a millionaire does not really care whether his money does good or not, provided he finds his conscience eased and his social status improved by giving it away..." -George Bernard Shaw.''
As illustrated in Shaw's quote, both intrinsic desires of conscience and extrinsic desires of social status may motivate giving. Warm glow has traditionally been restricted to intrinsic motivation,
however this distinction is often murky.
There has been considerable inconsistency in the literature as to whether a warm glow refers to
intrinsic
In science and engineering, an intrinsic property is a property of a specified subject that exists itself or within the subject. An extrinsic property is not essential or inherent to the subject that is being characterized. For example, mass i ...
or
extrinsic
In science and engineering, an intrinsic property is a property of a specified subject that exists itself or within the subject. An extrinsic property is not essential or inherent to the subject that is being characterized. For example, mass i ...
motivation.
According to Andreoni (2006), "putting warm-glow into the model is, while intuitively appealing, an admittedly ''ad hoc'' fix".
Further elaborating on the topic, he and colleagues wrote that the concept was "originally a placeholder for more specific models of individual and social motivations".
From this initial ambiguity, different authors have at times referred to the phenomenon as solely intrinsic,
both intrinsic and extrinsic,
or solely extrinsic.
Some authors have made deliberate distinctions between prestige-seeking (extrinsic) and the intrinsic components of warm glow,
but many have not.
Conceptualization of warm glow as either intrinsic or extrinsic has implications for
motivational crowding out,
satiation effects,
and expected magnitude.
Intrinsic warm glow
The most common and classically "correct" interpretation of warm glow is as a solely intrinsic phenomenon.
Language referring to the "joy of giving",
"the positive emotional experience from the act of helping others",
"the moral satisfaction of helping others" and the "internal satisfaction of giving" suggests an intrinsic drive. The intrinsic component of warm glow is the private emotional benefit to giving.
Extrinsic warm glow
Much of the ambiguity surrounding the motivational processes of warm glow has arisen from the misclassification of extrinsic rewards to intrinsic processes.
While intrinsic desires center upon emotional gains, extrinsic rewards may include recognition, identity signaling, and prestige. Extrinsic motivation may also take the form of punishment (negative warm glow), in the form of censure or blame.
Some research has explicitly focused on extrinsic warm glow, such as "relational warm glow".
One area that has been frequently confused in the literature involves the classification of guilt, which is an introjected form of extrinsic motivation.
Importance of motivational classification
The classification of warm glow as either intrinsic or extrinsic has important ramifications for policy makers.
The extensive body of literature on
motivational crowding out suggests the efficacy of policies promoting altruistic behavior may be a function of whether pre-existing behavior is intrinsically or extrinsically motivated.
The extent to which extrinsic incentives may be substitutes for intrinsic motivations depends upon the motivational classification of the warm glow model. Furthermore, intrinsic warm glow may be more resilient to satiation effects than extrinsic warm glow.
Finally, the expected magnitude of a warm glow will be a function of how it is characterized. Models assuming a purely intrinsic warm glow should report lesser warm glows than models also including extrinsic components.
Empathy and the psychological determinants of warm glow

The phenomenon of warm-glow giving was originally introduced as an economic model.
It its original form, the warm-glow model lacked a satisfactory explanation for the underlying psychological processes.
Early studies of warm glow were deliberately vague in attributing the experience to a cause.
A more recent body of research has identified several important determinants of warm glow, including social distance,
vividness to the beneficiary, and guilt avoidance.
Taken together, these observations suggest the warm glow may be best described as the visceral manifestation of
empathy
Empathy is generally described as the ability to take on another person's perspective, to understand, feel, and possibly share and respond to their experience. There are more (sometimes conflicting) definitions of empathy that include but are ...
.
This is consistent with the moral psychological literature of empathy, most notably as advanced by
Batson.
In his "empathy-altruism hypothesis", Batson claims that empathy ("feeling sympathetic, compassionate, warm, softhearted, tender") evokes a desire for other-regarding behavior.
Social distance
Social distance
In sociology, social distance describes the distance between individuals or social groups in society, including dimensions such as social class, race/ethnicity, gender or sexuality. Members of different groups mix less than members of the same g ...
is an important determinant of warm glow, particularly in the framework of empathy.
Prior research has examined the link between emotional arousal and social distance, finding that mutual suffering and shared joy both increase as a function of social similarity. Consistent with the "
identifiable victim effect
The identifiable victim effect is the tendency of individuals to offer greater aid when a specific, identifiable person ("victim") is observed under hardship, as compared to a large, vaguely defined group with the same need.
The identifiable vict ...
", research has shown that people express a greater willingness to help when others are known, as opposed to statistical.
Vividness to beneficiary
While the vividness of the beneficiary is captured in social distance,
the vividness to the beneficiary refers to a beneficiary's ability to perceive that kindness has been done upon them. As a determinant of warm glow, vividness to the beneficiary operates on two levels. The primary level concerns whether a beneficiary is aware that kindness has been given to them, absent any attribution of the source. The secondary level involves the identifiability of the benefactor. Warm glow should be positively impacted by both levels for vividness.
Guilt
Recent work has identified guilt avoidance as an important component of warm glow.
Some have even compared guilt as the "flip side" of warm glow. Parameterizing guilt as a component of warm glow allows for deficit values of warm glow, which was originally constrained to strictly positive values in Andreoni (1989, 1990).
In a recent publication, Andreoni and colleagues explain this by writing: ''"Psychologists posit that giving is initiated by a stimulus that elevates sympathy or empathy in the mind of the potential giver, much as the smell of freshly baked bread can pique appetite. Resolving this feeling comes either by giving and feeling good or by not giving and feeling guilt."''
In other notable overviews of warm glow, this phenomenon has been characterized as "personal distress".
In surveys of self-reported guilt, people experience roughly as much interpersonal and societal guilt as they do personal guilt. Furthermore, half of the survey respondents prefer to directly address and resolve their feelings of guilt. Taken together, these findings suggest a substantial component of guilt aversion.
Neurobiological evidence

Evidence from neural imaging supports the warm-glow effect. A meta-analysis of 36 studies using
functional magnetic resonance imaging
Functional magnetic resonance imaging or functional MRI (fMRI) measures brain activity by detecting changes associated with blood flow. This technique relies on the fact that cerebral blood flow and neuronal activation are coupled. When an area o ...
demonstrated that the brain's reward networks are consistently activated when choices to give are made. This includes the ventromedial prefrontal cortex (vmPFC). Strategic decisions for which something is hoped for in return activate more anterior regions of vmPFC but decisions where nothing is expected in return activate posterior regions of vmPFC. This provides a biological distinction of decisions to help that depends on the expectation of external rewards.
Applications
Voting

One of the earliest attempts to formally model the warm glow phenomenon can be found in "A Theory of the Calculus of Voting" by Riker and Ordeshook (1968).
Resolving the paradox by which rational individuals would never expend the effort to vote due to the statistical near-improbability of "having their vote count" (casting the decisive vote), Riker and Ordeshook highlighted the psychological utility of voting for one's preferred candidate. Just as an economic warm glow motivates people to willingly forego their scarce resources, the psychological utility described in early voting models serves to explain otherwise irrational behavior.
The warm glow of voting continues to be an important consideration in ethical voter models.
Environmental policy
In efforts to design effective, enduring, and efficient environmental interventions, many scholars and policy makers have focused on warm-glow effects.
Because many forms of extrinsic rewards and punishments have failed to promote long-term improvements in environmentally conscious behavior, there is a growing emphasis on intrinsic warm glow.
Intervention experiments offer promising results in areas such as supporting green energy,
recycling and waste reduction,
energy consumption,
carpooling initiatives.
Business
Corporate social responsibility
Supporting businesses engaged in
corporate social responsibility
Corporate social responsibility (CSR) or corporate social impact is a form of international private business industry self-regulation, self-regulation which aims to contribute to societal goals of a philanthropy, philanthropic, activist, or chari ...
(CSR) initiatives may give consumers a vicarious warm glow. However, recent research suggests that consumers may expect to overpay when companies engage in CSR due to perceptions of price fairness. The implication that "doing good" carries a financial burden for businesses leads consumers to infer general price markups. This body of research cautions that corporate warm glows may be coupled with "cold prickles" of extra costs.
Product advertising
Warm glow can be a central element of
cause marketing
Cause marketing is marketing done by a for-profit business that seeks to both increase profits and to better society in accordance with corporate social responsibility, such as by including activist messages in advertising.
A similar phrase, cau ...
, in which products are paired with donations. When consumers are exposed to products with a direct cause marketing association, their appraisal of both the product and the company may improve due to warm glow. There is also evidence that product warm glows may play a role in a process called "hedonic licensing", in which consumers who perceive a moral surplus subsequently allow themselves more leeway to make selfish purchases.
Capital Markets
Inefficiency in sustainable investments
Warm glow in the context of sustainable investments involves investors deriving a sense of satisfaction from their responsible
investment decision-making rather than from the actual impact. Private investors who engage in sustainable investments tend to rely on their emotions rather than adopting a calculated approach to evaluate the impact of their investment.
Hence, utility stems from the prosocial act itself and, therefore, does not increase linearly with the level of impact. This implies that investors’
willingness to pay
In behavioral economics, willingness to pay (WTP) is the maximum price at or below which a consumer will definitely buy one unit of a product. This corresponds to the standard economic view of a consumer reservation price. Some researchers, ho ...
is insensible to the level of impact of an investment.
The concept of warm glow stands in contrast to the conventional behavior outlined in
decision theory
Decision theory or the theory of rational choice is a branch of probability theory, probability, economics, and analytic philosophy that uses expected utility and probabilities, probability to model how individuals would behave Rationality, ratio ...
, often referred to as "
consequentialism
In moral philosophy, consequentialism is a class of normative, teleological ethical theories that holds that the consequences of one's conduct are the ultimate basis for judgement about the rightness or wrongness of that conduct. Thus, from a ...
", where the utility of prosocial investors is directly linked to the level of impact generated by their investments. Private investors showing warm glow behavior typically seek opportunities to prevent
climate change
Present-day climate change includes both global warming—the ongoing increase in Global surface temperature, global average temperature—and its wider effects on Earth's climate system. Climate variability and change, Climate change in ...
, leading to a higher
willingness to pay
In behavioral economics, willingness to pay (WTP) is the maximum price at or below which a consumer will definitely buy one unit of a product. This corresponds to the standard economic view of a consumer reservation price. Some researchers, ho ...
for investments with a sustainable impact than investments with no impact. Leveraging warm glow becomes important in attracting funds for sustainable investments, encouraging investors to integrate sustainability considerations into their financial decisions.
However, there are drawbacks when investors prioritize optimizing their warm glow over maximizing impact. Companies are incentivized to engage in
greenwashing
Greenwashing (a compound word modeled on "whitewash"), also called green sheen, is a form of advertising or marketing spin that deceptively uses green PR and green marketing to persuade the public that an organization's products, goals, or ...
or "impact-washing", promoting "light green"
financial products that provide emotional satisfaction but lack substantial impact. Warm glow is independent of investors’ sustainability experience, implying that enhanced sustainability accounting won’t contribute to realigning investors’
willingness to pay
In behavioral economics, willingness to pay (WTP) is the maximum price at or below which a consumer will definitely buy one unit of a product. This corresponds to the standard economic view of a consumer reservation price. Some researchers, ho ...
with the actual level of impact. To address this concern, positive externalities can be quantified in monetary terms so that investors adjust their willingness to pay coherently with the level of impact of the sustainable investment. Additionally, labels
could realign investors' emotional preferences with the quantitative level of impact of a financial product and incentivize firms to offer real "green" products.
Philanthropy
Avoidance behaviors
Common phenomena such as avoiding eye contact with beggars or adjusting one's route to avoid a solicitor may be explained using the warm glow model.
One behavioral consequence of warm glow is strategic avoidance of giving opportunities. According to this hypothesis, individuals anticipate their warm glow upon identifying a future giving opportunity. Assuming a functional form that allows warm glow to be negative (driven by a ''guilt'' of not giving), people may strategically and effortfully avoid giving situations. The strategic incentive is easily understood through the utility function
where the warm glow
is positive for a donation (joy of giving) and negative for not giving (guilt). For an agent who would suffer a disutility of giving at their desired level
because the
marginal utility
Marginal utility, in mainstream economics, describes the change in ''utility'' (pleasure or satisfaction resulting from the consumption) of one unit of a good or service. Marginal utility can be positive, negative, or zero. Negative marginal utilit ...
of private expenditure
exceeds the marginal utility of warm-glow giving, they should prefer to give nothing
Because giving nothing may be associated with guilt, the utility of
will be negative. Therefore, for a rational agent who cannot justify giving,
, can maximize their utility through avoiding a giving situation, effectively dropping the warm glow argument from their utility functions.
Thus,
suggests avoidance of giving opportunities is a preferred strategy for individuals who experience guilt as a negative warm glow. Economic models assign a cost of effort to avoidance, and predict that people will incur such effort whenever
where
is the utility of not giving,
is the cost of avoidance, and
is the utility of giving to a solicitor, conditional upon not avoiding.
Through this lens, avoidance can be viewed as an economic
commitment device
A commitment device is, according to journalist Stephen J. Dubner and economist Steven Levitt, a way to lock oneself into following a plan of action that one might not want to do, but which one knows is good for oneself. In other words, a commit ...
, where a person commits to avoiding a situation (being asked to give) in which they are likely to surrender to temptation (giving). Central to this avoidance hypothesis is that individuals can anticipate their behavior in high-empathy "hot states", while in low-empathy "cold states". While this model assumes a high degree of sophistication on the part of the individual, research by Andreoni, Rao, and Trachtman explores this very phenomenon by observing avoidance and donation behavior of customers entering a supermarket during the holidays. Customers often walked to a further entrance to avoid solicitors for the Salvation Army. According to their model, "empathetically vulnerable" individuals who are not able to give (for budgetary reasons), faced the greatest incentive to avoid collectors because of the guilt they would experience upon saying "no".
Grouping behaviors
Charities may strategically employ categorical
donor recognition. For example, a charitable organization may distinguish any gift between $500-$999.99 by a title distinct from that awarded for gifts above $1,000. As a consequence, the social signaling component of the warm-glow effect (in extrinsic operationalizations of warm glow) suggests individuals should be motivated to make the minimum donation to acquire their desired categorical status. Consistent with this hypothesis, research has indicated significant grouping behavior of donors around category minimums.
Inefficiency in charitable allocation
A majority of those who choose to give some portion of their wealth to charity support multiple different causes. Rather than giving 100% of their cumulative donations to the same source, there exists a widespread preference to distribute funds across charities.
The warm glow model explains this by recognizing that givers receive multiple warm glows through giving to multiple causes, thus supporting the preference to make multiple small contributions. As a consequence, some scholars suggest an efficiency loss due to high volumes of small donations – which are less efficient to process — rather than fewer large donations. Moral philosopher
Peter Singer
Peter Albert David Singer (born 6 July 1946) is an Australian moral philosopher who is Emeritus Ira W. DeCamp Professor of Bioethics at Princeton University. Singer's work specialises in applied ethics, approaching the subject from a secu ...
mentions warm-glow givers in his 2015 book, ''
The Most Good You Can Do
''The Most Good You Can Do: How Effective Altruism Is Changing Ideas About Living Ethically'' is a 2015 Yale University Press book by moral philosopher and bioethicist Peter Singer describing and arguing for the ideas of effective altruism. As a ...
''. Singer states that these types of donors "give small amounts to many charities
ndare not so interested in whether what they are doing helps others." He references "empathetic concern" and "personal distress" as two distinct components of warm-glow givers.
Inefficiency in charitable selection
Warm glow may offer an explanation for some of the observed inefficiencies in charitable giving. For example, United States citizens directed more than 60% of their total charitable contributions to religious groups, education institutions, art organizations, and foundations in 2017; compared to under 7% in foreign aid. According to models of social justice
and economic
QALYs,
in which human lives are treated with equal dignity and equal respect - regardless of race, gender, or place of origin - the goal of charity should be to fight global poverty. Similarly, economic models, which attempt to place a monetary value on the human life, highlight the inefficiency of all philanthropy not used to combat global poverty, which offers the highest marginal return.
The warm-glow model accounts for such inefficiency because impure altruists may be insensitive to the actual cause, and more sensitive to the act of giving or size of the gift. Thus, warm-glow may generate philanthropic inefficiencies to the extent that it desensitizes potential donors to the marginal impact of a given charity. In response to this concern,
William MacAskill
William David MacAskill (' Crouch; born 24 March 1987) is a Scottish philosopher and author, as well as one of the originators of the effective altruism movement. He was a Research Fellow at the Global Priorities Institute at the University of ...
and colleagues have advanced a process of philanthropic allocation called "
effective altruism
Effective altruism (EA) is a 21st-century philosophical and social movement that advocates impartially calculating benefits and prioritizing causes to provide the greatest good. It is motivated by "using evidence and reason to figure out how to b ...
".
This methodology seeks to leverage logic and responsibility to identify effective charitable opportunities, thus minimizing the effect of warm-glow in the decision-making process.
Technology
Warm-glow has been found to influence user behavioral intention to adopt a technology.
Criticisms
Ad-hoc
A common criticism of the warm-glow paradigm is that it seems ad-hoc. Indeed, Andreoni, the father of the original model, stated that "putting warm-glow into the model is, while intuitively appealing, an admittedly ''ad hoc'' fix."
As the body of research has evolved over nearly 30 years — incorporating philosophical,
psychological,
and physiological insights
[{{]
Evidence from neural imaging supports the warm-glow effect. A meta-analysis of 36 studies using ]functional magnetic resonance imaging
Functional magnetic resonance imaging or functional MRI (fMRI) measures brain activity by detecting changes associated with blood flow. This technique relies on the fact that cerebral blood flow and neuronal activation are coupled. When an area o ...
to observe brains of individuals making decisions to give to others demonstrated that reward networks are consistently activated when giving to others. This includes the ventromedial prefrontal cortex (vmPFC). However, decisions where something was expected in return primarily activate anterior regions of the whereas decisions where nothing was expected in return activated posterior regions of vmPFC. This provided a biological distinction of helping decisions depending on the expectation of exogenous reward. A comparative fMRI meta-analysis of altruistic and strategic decisions to give.
Other applications
Public Health
One application of warm-glow giving is in pay-it-forward sexually transmitted disease (STD) testing. A gay man is given a free STD test alongside messages from the community. After they receive the test, they are asked about donating to support subsequent gay men to receive STD tests. A quasi-experimental study demonstrated that pay-it-forward increased STD testing. – it has become a better descriptive model of behavior.
Self-delusion
An obscure criticism of the warm-glow paradigm is that it necessitates self-deception. This argument states that in order to reap the emotional reward of helping others, one must believe his actions to be motivated altruistically. Yet, the mere existence of a warm glow should then contradict the belief of pure altruism. A question arises as to whether prolonged self-delusion is sustainable and impervious to learning through Self-perception theory, self-perception.
Extensions
Some research has investigated the link between warm glow and the phenomenon of mere exposure
The mere-exposure effect is a psychological phenomenon by which people tend to develop a liking or disliking for things merely because they are familiar with them. In social psychology, this effect is sometimes called the familiarity principle. Th ...
, leading researchers to consider warm glow as a heuristic
A heuristic or heuristic technique (''problem solving'', '' mental shortcut'', ''rule of thumb'') is any approach to problem solving that employs a pragmatic method that is not fully optimized, perfected, or rationalized, but is nevertheless ...
.[{{Cite journal, last=Monin, first=Benoît, date=2003, title=The Warm Glow Heuristic: When Liking Leads to Familiarity., journal=Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, volume=85, issue=6, pages=1035–1048, doi=10.1037/0022-3514.85.6.1035, pmid=14674812, issn=1939-1315]
References
{{Reflist, 30em
Further reading
*{{cite book , chapter=Models Involving ‘Warm Glow’ , title=Behavioral Economics and Its Applications , first1=Peter , last1=Diamond , first2=Hannu , last2=Vartiainen , publisher=Princeton University Press , year=2012 , pages=62–65 , isbn=978-1-4008-2914-9
*{{cite book , last=Andreoni , first=James , chapter=Philanthropy , title=Handbook of the Economics of Giving, Altruism and Reciprocity: Applications , editor1-first=Serge-Christophe , editor1-last=Kolm , editor2-first=Jean Mercier , editor2-last=Ythier , publisher=Elsevier , year=2006 , pages=1202–1223 , isbn=978-0-444-52145-3
{{Charity
{{DEFAULTSORT:Warm-Glow Giving
Altruism
Behavioral economics
Moral psychology