Truthful resource allocation is the problem of allocating resources among agents with different valuations over the resources, such that agents are incentivized to reveal their true valuations over the resources.
Model
There are ''m'' resources that are assumed to be ''homogeneous'' and ''divisible''. Examples are:
* Materials, such as wood or metal;
* Virtual resources, such as CPU time or computer memory;
* Financial resources, such as shares in firms.
There are ''n'' agents. Each agent has a function that attributes a numeric value to each "bundle" (combination of resources).
It is often assumed that the agents' value functions are ''linear'', so that if the agent receives a fraction ''r
j'' of each resource ''j'', then his/her value is the sum of ''r
j'' *''v
j'' .
Design goals
The goal is to design a
truthful mechanism In game theory, an asymmetric game where players have private information is said to be strategy-proof or strategyproof (SP) if it is a weakly-dominant strategy for every player to reveal his/her private information, i.e. given no information abou ...
, that will induce the agents to reveal their true value functions, and then calculate an allocation that satisfies some fairness and efficiency objectives. The common efficiency objectives are:
*
''Pareto efficiency'' (PE);
*''
Utilitarian
In ethical philosophy, utilitarianism is a family of normative ethical theories that prescribe actions that maximize happiness and well-being for all affected individuals.
Although different varieties of utilitarianism admit different charact ...
social welfare'' --- defined as the sum of agents' utilities. An allocation maximizing this sum is called ''utilitarian'' or ''max-sum''; it is always PE.
*''Nash social welfare ---'' defined as the product of agents' utilities. An allocation maximizing this product is called ''Nash-optimal'' or ''max-product'' or ''proportionally-fair''; it is always PE. When agents have
additive utilities
In economics, additive utility is a cardinal utility function with the sigma additivity property.
Additivity (also called ''linearity'' or ''modularity'') means that "the whole is equal to the sum of its parts." That is, the utility of a set of ...
, it is equivalent to the ''
competitive equilibrium
Competitive equilibrium (also called: Walrasian equilibrium) is a concept of economic equilibrium introduced by Kenneth Arrow and Gérard Debreu in 1951 appropriate for the analysis of commodity markets with flexible prices and many traders, and s ...
from equal incomes''.
The most common fairness objectives are:
* Equal treatment of equals (ETE) --- if two agents have exactly the same utility function, then they should get exactly the same utility.
*
Envy-freeness Envy-freeness, also known as no-envy, is a criterion for fair division. It says that, when resources are allocated among people with equal rights, each person should receive a share that is, in their eyes, at least as good as the share received by ...
--- no agent should envy another agent. It implies ETE.
Trivial algorithms
Two trivial truthful algorithms are:
* The equal split algorithm --- which gives each agent exactly 1/''n'' of each resource. This allocation is envy-free (and obviously ETE), but usually it is very inefficient.
* The
serial dictatorship algorithm --- which orders the agents arbitrarily, and lets each agent in turn take all resources that he wants, from among the remaining ones. This allocation is PE, but usually it is unfair.
It is possible to mix these two mechanisms, and get a truthful mechanism that is partly-fair and partly-efficient.
But the ideal mechanism would satisfy all three properties simultaneously: truthfulness, efficiency and fairness.
At most one object per agent
In a variant of the resource allocation problem, sometimes called one-sided matching or assignment, the total amount of objects allocated to each agent must be at most 1.
When there are 2 agents and 2 objects, the following mechanism satisfies all three properties: if each agent prefers a different object, give each agent his preferred object; if both agents prefer the same object, give each agent 1/2 of each object (It is PE due to the capacity constraints). However, when there are 3 or more agents, it may be impossible to attain all three properties.
Zhou
proved that, when there are 3 or more agents, each agent must get at most 1 object, and each object must be given to at most 1 agent, no truthful mechanism satisfies both PE and ETE.
* When there are multiple units of each object (but each agent must still get at most 1 object), there is a weaker impossibility result: no PE and ETE mechanism satisfies
Group strategyproofness.
* He leaves open the more general resource allocation setting, in which each agent may get more than one object.
There are analogous impossibility results for agents with
ordinal utilities:
* For agents with ''strict ordinal'' utilities, Bogomolnaia and Moulin
prove that no mechanism satisfies possible-PE, necessary-truthfulness, and ETE.
* For agents with ''weak ordinal'' utilities, Katta and Sethuraman
prove that no mechanism satisfies possible-PE, possible-truthfulness, and necessary-envy-freeness.
See also: Truthful one-sided matching.
Approximation Algorithms
There are several truthful algorithms that find a constant-factor approxiamtion of the maximum utilitarian or Nash welfare.
Guo and Conitzer studied the special case of ''n''=2 agents. For the case of ''m''=2 resources, they showed a truthful mechanism attaining 0.828 of the maximum utilitarian welfare, and showed an upper bound of 0.841. For the case of many resources, they showed that all truthful mechanisms of the same kind approach 0.5 of the maximum utilitarian welfare. Their mechanisms are complete - they allocate all the resources.
Cole, Gkatzelis and Goel studied mechanisms of a different kind - based on the max-product allocation. For ''many agents'', with valuations that are
homogeneous function
In mathematics, a homogeneous function is a function of several variables such that, if all its arguments are multiplied by a scalar, then its value is multiplied by some power of this scalar, called the degree of homogeneity, or simply the '' ...
s, they show a truthful mechanism called
Partial Allocation that guarantees to each agent at least 1/''e'' ≈ 0.368 of his/her utility in the max-product allocation. Their mechanism is
envy-free Envy-freeness, also known as no-envy, is a criterion for fair division. It says that, when resources are allocated among people with equal rights, each person should receive a share that is, in their eyes, at least as good as the share received by a ...
when the valuations are additive linear functions. They show that no truthful mechanism can guarantee to all agents more than 0.5 of their max-product utility.
For the special case of ''n=2 agents'', they show a truthful mechanism that attains at least 0.622 of the utilitarian welfare. They also show that the mechanism running the ''equal-split'' mechanism and the ''partial-allocation'' mechanism, and choosing the outcome with the highest social welfare, is still truthful, since both agents always prefer the ''same'' outcome. Moreover, it attains at least 2/3 of the optimal welfare. They also show an
algorithm for computing the max-product allocation, and show that the Nash-optimal allocation itself attains at least 0.933 of the utilitarian welfare.
They also show a mechanism called Strong Demand Matching, which is tailored for a setting with many agents and few resources (such as the
privatization
Privatization (also privatisation in British English) can mean several different things, most commonly referring to moving something from the public sector into the private sector. It is also sometimes used as a synonym for deregulation when ...
auction in the
Czech republic
The Czech Republic, or simply Czechia, is a landlocked country in Central Europe. Historically known as Bohemia, it is bordered by Austria to the south, Germany to the west, Poland to the northeast, and Slovakia to the southeast. Th ...
). The mechanism guarantees to each agent at least ''p''/(''p''+1) of the max-product utility, when ''p'' is the smallest equilibrium price of a resource when each agent has a unit budget. When there are many more agents than resources, the price of each resource is usually high, so the approximation factor approaches 1. In particular, when there are two resources, this fraction is at least ''n''/(''n''+1). This mechanism assigns to each agent a fraction of a single resource.
Cheung improved the competitive ratios of previous works:
* The ratio for two agents
and two resources improved from 0.828 to 5/6 ≈ 0.833 with a co
mplete-allocation mechanism, and strictly more than 5/6 with a partial-allocation mechanism. The upper bound improved from 0.841 to 5/6+epsilon for a complete-allocation mechanism, and to 0.8644 for a partial mechanism.
* The ratio for two agents and many resources improved from 2/3 to 0.67776, by using a we
ighted average of two mechanisms: partial-allocation, and max (partial-allocation, equal-split).
Related problems
*
Truthful cake-cutting Truthful cake-cutting is the study of algorithms for fair cake-cutting that are also truthful mechanisms, i.e., they incentivize the participants to reveal their true valuations to the various parts of the cake.
The classic divide and choose proced ...
- a variant of the problem in which there is a single heterogeneous resource ("cake"), and each agent has a personal value-measure over the resource.
*
Strategic fair division
Strategic fair division is the branch of fair division in which the participants are assumed to hide their preferences and act strategically in order to maximize their own utility, rather than playing sincerely according to their true preferences ...
- the study of equilibria of fair division games when the agents act strategically rather than sincerely.
*Truthful allocation of two kinds of resources - plentiful and scarce.
*Truthful fair division of indivisible items.
[{{Cite journal, last1=Amanatidis, first1=Georgios, last2=Birmpas, first2=Georgios, last3=Christodoulou, first3=George, last4=Markakis, first4=Evangelos, date=2017, title=Truthful Allocation Mechanisms Without Payments: Characterization and Implications on Fairness, arxiv=1705.10706, journal=Proceedings of the 2017 ACM Conference on Economics and Computation - EC '17, pages=545–562, doi=10.1145/3033274.3085147, bibcode=2017arXiv170510706A, s2cid=27249301]
References
Mechanism design
Fair division protocols