Round-robin Item Allocation
   HOME

TheInfoList



OR:

Round robin is a procedure for
fair item allocation Fair item allocation is a kind of the fair division problem in which the items to divide are ''discrete'' rather than continuous. The items have to be divided among several partners who potentially value them differently, and each item has to be gi ...
. It can be used to allocate several indivisible items among several people, such that the allocation is "almost"
envy-free Envy-freeness, also known as no-envy, is a criterion for fair division. It says that, when resources are allocated among people with equal rights, each person should receive a share that is, in their eyes, at least as good as the share received by ...
: each agent believes that the bundle they received is at least as good as the bundle of any other agent, when at most one item is removed from the other bundle. In sports, the round-robin procedure is called a
draft Draft, the draft, or draught may refer to: Watercraft dimensions * Draft (hull), the distance from waterline to keel of a vessel * Draft (sail), degree of curvature in a sail * Air draft, distance from waterline to the highest point on a v ...
.


Setting

There are ''m'' objects to allocate, and ''n'' people ("agents") with equal rights to these objects. Each person has different preferences over the objects. The preferences of an agent are given by a vector of values - a value for each object. It is assumed that the value of a bundle for an agent is the sum of the values of the objects in the bundle (in other words, the agents' valuations are an
additive set function In mathematics, an additive set function is a function \mu mapping sets to numbers, with the property that its value on a union of two disjoint sets equals the sum of its values on these sets, namely, \mu(A \cup B) = \mu(A) + \mu(B). If this ad ...
on the set of objects).


Description

The protocol proceeds as follows: # Number the people arbitrarily from 1 to n; # While there are unassigned objects: #* Let each person from 1 to n pick an unassigned object. It is assumed that each person in their turn picks an unassigned object with a highest value among the remaining objects.


Additivity requirement

The round-robin protocol requires additivity, since it requires each agent to pick their "best item" without knowing what other items they are going to get; additivity of valuations guarantees that there is always a "best item" (an item with a highest value). In other words, it assumes that the items are
independent goods Independent goods are goods that have a zero cross elasticity of demand. Changes in the price of one good will have no effect on the demand for an independent good. Thus independent goods are neither complements nor substitutes. For example, ...
. The additivity requirement can be relaxed to weak additivity.


Properties

The round-robin protocol is very simple to execute: it requires only ''m'' steps. Each agent can order the objects in advance by descending value (this takes O(m \textm) time per agent) and then pick an object in time O(1). The final allocation is EF1 - envy-free up to one object. This means that, for every pair of agents i and j, if at most one object is removed from the bundle of j, then i does not envy j. : ''Proof:'' For every agent i, divide the selections made by the agents to sub-sequences: the first subsequence starts at agent 1 and ends at agent i-1; the latter subsequences start at i and end at i-1. In the latter subsequences, agent i chooses first, so they can choose their best item, so they do not envy any other agent. Agent i can envy only one of the agents 1,...,i-1, and the envy comes only from an item they selected in the first subsequence. If this item is removed, agent i does not envy. Additionally, round-robin guarantees that each agent receives the same number of items (''m''/''n'', if ''m'' is divisible by ''n''), or almost the same number of items (if ''m'' is not divisible by ''n''). Thus, it is useful in situations with simple cardinality constraints, such as: assigning course-seats to students where each student must receive the same number of courses.


Efficiency considerations

Round-robin guarantees approximate fairness, but the outcome might be inefficient. As a simple example, suppose the valuations are: Round-robin, when Alice chooses first, yields the allocation (zxv, ywu) with utilities (24,23) and social welfare 47. It is not
Pareto efficient In welfare economics, a Pareto improvement formalizes the idea of an outcome being "better in every possible way". A change is called a Pareto improvement if it leaves at least one person in society better off without leaving anyone else worse ...
, since it is dominated e.g. y the allocation (yxw, zvu), with utilities (25,25). An alternative algorithm, which may attain a higher social welfare, is the ''Iterated maximum-weight matching'' algorithm. In each iteration, it finds a maximum-weight matching in the
bipartite graph In the mathematics, mathematical field of graph theory, a bipartite graph (or bigraph) is a Graph (discrete mathematics), graph whose vertex (graph theory), vertices can be divided into two disjoint sets, disjoint and Independent set (graph theo ...
in which the nodes are the agents and the items, and the edge weights are the agents' values to the items. In the above example, the first matching is (y,z), the second is (w,x), and the third is (u,v). The total allocation is (ywu,zxv) with utilities (18,32); the social welfare (- the sum of utilities) is 50, which is higher than in the round-robin allocation. Note that even iterated maximum-weight matching does not guarantee Pareto efficiency, as the above allocation is dominated by (xwv, zyu) with utilities (19,36).


Strategy considerations

Round-robin is not a
truthful mechanism In mechanism design, a strategyproof (SP) mechanism is a game form in which each player has a weakly- dominant strategy, so that no player can gain by "spying" over the other players to know what they are going to play. When the players have privat ...
. As an example, suppose there are 60 items which Alice values at 60,59,...,2,1. George ranks the items as follows (where we use Alice's valuation as the item name): 59 > 57 > ... > 3 > 1 > 2 > 4 > ... > 58 > 60. Alice plays first. If she reports her true valuations, she gets the thirty even-valued items (60,58,...,4,2) as George takes the thirty odd-valued ones, so Alice's value is 930. But if Alice reports 59 > 57 > .., > 25 > 23 > 60 > 58 > ... > 24 > 22 > ... then she first gets ten odd-valued items 59, 55, ..., 27, 23 and then 20 even-valued ones 60, 58, ..., 24, 22, and her value is 410+820=1230. Instead of the ten low-valued even items 2,...,20 she got ten high-valued odd items; her gain is 21 + 23 + ... + 37 + 39 = 300.


Round-robin for groups

The round-robin algorithm can be used to fairly allocate items among groups. In this setting, all members in each group consume the same bundle, but different members in each group may have different preferences over the items. This raises the question of how each group should decide which item to choose in its turn. Suppose that the goal of each group is to maximize the fraction of its members that are "happy", that is, feel that the allocation is fair (according to their personal preferences). Suppose also that the agents have binary additive valuations, that is, each agent values each item at either 1 ("approve") or 0 ("disapprove"). Then, each group can decide what item to pick using ''weighted
approval voting Approval voting is a single-winner rated voting system where voters can approve of all the candidates as they like instead of Plurality voting, choosing one. The method is designed to eliminate vote-splitting while keeping election administration ...
'': * Each group member is assigned a weight. The weight of member ''j'' is a certain function ''w''(''rj'',''sj''), where: ** ''rj'' is the number of remaining goods that ''j'' approves; ** ''sj'' is the number of goods that ''j'''s group should still get such that the chosen fairness criterion is satisfied for ''j''. * Each remaining item is assigned a weight. The weight of item ''g'' is the sum of weights of the agents who approve ''g'': sum of ''w''(''rj'',''sj'') for all ''j'' such that ''j'' values ''g'' at 1. * The group picks an item with the largest weight. The resulting algorithm is called RWAV (round-robin with weighted approval voting). The weight function ''w''(''r'',''s'') is determined based on an auxiliary function ''B''(''r'',''s''), defined by the following recurrence relation: * B(r,s) := 1 ~~\text~~ s\leq 0; * B(r,s) := 0 ~~\text~~ 0 * B(r,s) := \min\bigg \frac[B(r-1,s)+B(r-1,s-1), B(r-2,s-1) \bigg">(r-1,s)+B(r-1,s-1).html" ;"title="\frac[B(r-1,s)+B(r-1,s-1)">\frac[B(r-1,s)+B(r-1,s-1), B(r-2,s-1) \bigg~~\text. Intuitively, B(''r'',''s'') of an agent represents the probability that the agent is happy with the final allocation. If ''s'' ≤ 0, then by definition this probability is 1: the agent needs no more goods to be happy. If 0<''s'' and ''r''<''s'', then this probability is 0: the agent cannot be happy, since they need more goods than are available. Otherwise, B(''r'',''s'') is the average between B(''r''-1,''s'') - when the other group takes a good wanted by the agent, and B(''r''-1,''s-1'') - when the agent's group takes a good wanted by the agent. The term B(''r''-2,''s''-1) represents the situation when both groups take a good wanted by the agent. Once B(''r'',''s'') is computed, the weight function ''w'' is defined as follows:
w(r,s) := B(r,s) - B(r-1,s)
When using this weight function and running RWAV with two groups, the fraction of happy members in group 1 is at least B(''r'', s(''r'')), and the fraction of happy members in group 2 is at least B(''r''-1, s(''r'')). The function ''s''(''r'') is determined by the fairness criterion. For example, for 1-out-of-3 maximin-share fairness, ''s''(''r'') = floor(''r''/3). The following table shows some values of the function ''B'', with the values of B(r-1, floor(r/3)) boldfaced: From this one can conclude that the RWAV algorithm guarantees that, in both groups, at least 75% of the members feel that the allocation is 1-out-of-3 MMS fair.


Extensions

1. The round-robin protocol guarantees EF1 when the items are ''goods'' (- valued positively by all agents) and when they are ''chores'' (- valued negatively by all agents). However, when there are both goods and chores, it does not guarantee EF1. An adaptation of round-robin called double round-robin guarantees EF1 even with a mixture of goods and chores. 2. When agents have more complex cardinality constraints (i.e., the items are divided into categories, and for each category of items, there is an upper bound on the number of items each agent can get from this category), round-robin might fail. However, combining round-robin with the envy-graph procedure gives an algorithm that finds allocations that are both EF1 and satisfy the cardinality constraints. 3. When agents have different weights (i.e., agents have different entitlement for the total items), a generalized round-robin protocol called weighted round-robin guarantees EF1 when the items are ''goods'' (- valued positively by all agents) and the reversed weighted round-robin guarantees EF1 when the items are ''chores'' (-valued negatively by all agents).


See also

Round-robin is a special case of a
picking sequence A picking sequence is a protocol for fair item assignment. Suppose ''m'' items have to be divided among ''n'' agents. One way to allocate the items is to let one agent select a single item, then let another agent select a single item, and so on. A ...
. Round-robin protocols are used in other areas besides fair item allocation. For example, see
round-robin scheduling Round-robin (RR) is one of the algorithms employed by process and network schedulers in computing. Guowang Miao, Jens Zander, Ki Won Sung, and Ben Slimane, Fundamentals of Mobile Data Networks, Cambridge University Press, , 2016. As the term ...
and
round-robin tournament A round-robin tournament or all-play-all tournament is a competition format in which each contestant meets every other participant, usually in turn.''Webster's Third New International Dictionary of the English Language, Unabridged'' (1971, G. & ...
.


References

{{reflist Fair division protocols