In
apportionment theory, rank-index methods
are a set of
apportionment method
Apportionment is the process by which seats in a legislative body are distributed among administrative divisions, such as states or parties, entitled to representation. This page presents the general principles and issues related to apportionment. ...
s that generalize the
divisor method. These have also been called Huntington methods,
since they generalize an idea by
Edward Vermilye Huntington
Edward Vermilye Huntington (April 26, 1874November 25, 1952) was an American mathematician.
Biography
Huntington was awarded the B.A. and the M.A. by Harvard University in 1895 and 1897, respectively. After two years' teaching at Williams College ...
.
Input and output
Like all apportionment methods, the inputs of any rank-index method are:
* A positive integer
representing the total number of items to allocate. It is also called the ''house size.''
* A positive integer
representing the number of ''agents'' to which items should be allocated. For example, these can be
federal states or
political parties
A political party is an organization that coordinates candidates to compete in a particular area's elections. It is common for the members of a party to hold similar ideas about politics, and parties may promote specific ideological or p ...
.
* A vector of fractions
with
, representing ''entitlements'' -
represents the
entitlement
Entitled or Entitlement may refer to:
Social sciences and philosophy
* Entitlement (fair division)
* Entitlement program
* Entitlement commodities
* Entitlement (psychology)
In psychology, entitlement mentality is defined as a sense of deserv ...
of agent
, that is, the fraction of items to which
is entitled (out of the total of
).
Its output is a vector of integers
with
, called an apportionment of
, where
is the number of items allocated to agent ''i''.
Iterative procedure
Every rank-index method is parametrized by a ''rank-index function''
, which is increasing in the entitlement ''
'' and decreasing in the current allocation
. The apportionment is computed iteratively as follows:
* Initially, set
to 0 for all parties.
* At each iteration, allocate one item to an agent for whom
is maximum (break ties arbitrarily).
* Stop after
iterations.
Divisor methods are a special case of rank-index methods: a divisor method with divisor function
is equivalent to a rank-index method with rank-index function
.
Min-max formulation
Every rank-index method can be defined using a min-max inequality: a is an allocation for the rank-index method with function ''r'', if-and-only-if:
.
Properties
Every rank-index method is
''house-monotone''. This means that, when
increases, the allocation of each agent weakly increases. This immediately follows from the iterative procedure.
Every rank-index method is ''uniform''. This means that, we take some subset of the agents
, and apply the same method to their combined allocation, then the result is exactly the vector
. In other words: every part of a fair allocation is fair too. This immediately follows from the min-max inequality.
Moreover:
* Every apportionment method that is ''uniform'', ''symmetric'' and ''
balanced
In telecommunications and professional audio, a balanced line or balanced signal pair is an electrical circuit consisting of two conductors of the same type, both of which have equal impedances along their lengths, to ground, and to other c ...
'' must be a rank-index method.
* Every apportionment method that is ''uniform'',
''house-monotone'' and ''
balanced
In telecommunications and professional audio, a balanced line or balanced signal pair is an electrical circuit consisting of two conductors of the same type, both of which have equal impedances along their lengths, to ground, and to other c ...
'' must be a rank-index method.
Quota-capped divisor methods
A ''quota-capped divisor method'' is an apportionment method where we begin by assigning every state its lower quota of seats. Then, we add seats one-by-one to the state with the highest votes-per-seat average, so long as adding an additional seat does not result in the state exceeding its upper quota.
However, quota-capped divisor methods violate the
participation criterion
The participation criterion is a voting system criterion that says candidates should never lose an election as a result of receiving too many votes in support. More formally, it says that adding more voters who prefer ''Alice'' to ''Bob'' should ...
(also called
population monotonicity)—it is possible for a party to ''lose'' a seat as a result of winning ''more'' votes.
Every quota-capped divisor method satisfies
house monotonicity
House monotonicity (also called house-size monotonicity) is a property of apportionment methods. These are methods for allocating seats in a parliament among federal states (or among political parties). The property says that, if the number of se ...
. Moreover, quota-capped divisor methods satisfy the
quota rule
In mathematics and political science, the quota rule describes a desired property of proportional apportionment methods. It says that the number of seats allocated to a party should be equal to their entitlement plus or minus one.Michael J. Caul ...
.
However, quota-capped divisor methods violate the
participation criterion
The participation criterion is a voting system criterion that says candidates should never lose an election as a result of receiving too many votes in support. More formally, it says that adding more voters who prefer ''Alice'' to ''Bob'' should ...
(also called
population monotonicity)—it is possible for a party to ''lose'' a seat as a result of winning ''more'' votes.
This occurs when:
# Party ''i'' gets more votes.
# Because of the greater divisor, the upper quota of some other party ''j'' decreases. Therefore, party ''j'' is not eligible to a seat in the current iteration, and some third party receives the seat instead.
# Then, at the next iteration, party ''j'' is again eligible to win a seat and it beats party ''i''.
Moreover, quota-capped versions of other algorithms frequently violate the true quota in the presence of error (e.g. census miscounts). Jefferson's method frequently violates the true quota, even after being quota-capped, while Webster's method and Huntington-Hill perform well even without quota-caps.
References
{{voting systems
Mathematical theorems
Apportionment methods