HOME

TheInfoList



OR:

In
mathematics Mathematics is a field of study that discovers and organizes methods, Mathematical theory, theories and theorems that are developed and Mathematical proof, proved for the needs of empirical sciences and mathematics itself. There are many ar ...
and
fair division Fair division is the problem in game theory of dividing a set of resources among several people who have an Entitlement (fair division), entitlement to them so that each person receives their due share. The central tenet of fair division is that ...
, apportionment problems involve dividing (''apportioning'') a
whole number An integer is the number zero ( 0), a positive natural number (1, 2, 3, ...), or the negation of a positive natural number ( −1, −2, −3, ...). The negations or additive inverses of the positive natural numbers are referred to as negative ...
of identical goods fairly across several parties with real-valued
entitlements An entitlement is a government program guaranteeing access to some benefit by members of a specific group and based on established rights or by legislation. A "right" is itself an entitlement associated with a moral or social principle, while an ...
. The original, and best-known, example of an apportionment problem involves distributing seats in a
legislature A legislature (, ) is a deliberative assembly with the legal authority to make laws for a political entity such as a country, nation or city on behalf of the people therein. They are often contrasted with the executive and judicial power ...
between different federal states or
political parties A political party is an organization that coordinates candidates to compete in a particular area's elections. It is common for the members of a party to hold similar ideas about politics, and parties may promote specific ideological or p ...
. However, apportionment methods can be applied to other situations as well, including bankruptcy problems,
inheritance law Inheritance is the practice of receiving private property, titles, debts, entitlements, privileges, rights, and obligations upon the death of an individual. The rules of inheritance differ among societies and have changed over time. Offici ...
(e.g. dividing animals), manpower planning (e.g. demographic quotas), and rounding
percentages In mathematics, a percentage () is a number or ratio expressed as a fraction of 100. It is often denoted using the ''percent sign'' (%), although the abbreviations ''pct.'', ''pct'', and sometimes ''pc'' are also used. A percentage is a dimen ...
. Mathematically, an apportionment method is just a method of
rounding Rounding or rounding off is the process of adjusting a number to an approximate, more convenient value, often with a shorter or simpler representation. For example, replacing $ with $, the fraction 312/937 with 1/3, or the expression √2 with ...
real numbers to natural numbers. Despite the simplicity of this problem, every method of rounding suffers one or more
paradoxes A paradox is a logically self-contradictory statement or a statement that runs contrary to one's expectation. It is a statement that, despite apparently valid reasoning from true or apparently true premises, leads to a seemingly self-contradictor ...
, as proven by the Balinski–Young theorem. The mathematical theory of apportionment identifies what properties can be expected from an apportionment method. The mathematical theory of apportionment was studied as early as 1907 by the mathematician
Agner Krarup Erlang Agner Krarup Erlang (1 January 1878 – 3 February 1929) was a Danish mathematician, statistician and engineer, who invented the fields of traffic engineering and queueing theory. Erlang's 1909 paper, and subsequent papers over the decades, a ...
. It was later developed to a great detail by the mathematician
Michel Balinski Michel Louis Balinski (born Michał Ludwik Baliński; October 6, 1933 – February 4, 2019) was an American and French applied mathematician, economist, operations research analyst and political scientist. Educated in the United States, from 198 ...
and the economist
Peyton Young Hobart Peyton Young (born March 9, 1945) is an American game theorist and economist known for his contributions to evolutionary game theory and its application to the study of institutional and technological change, as well as the theory of lea ...
.


Definitions


Input

The inputs to an apportionment method are: * A positive integer h representing the total number of items to allocate. It is also called the ''house size'', since in many cases, the items to allocate are seats in a house of representatives. *A positive integer n representing the number of ''agents'' to which items should be allocated. For example, these can be federal states or
political parties A political party is an organization that coordinates candidates to compete in a particular area's elections. It is common for the members of a party to hold similar ideas about politics, and parties may promote specific ideological or p ...
. * A vector of numbers (t_1,\ldots,t_n) representing ''entitlements'' - t_i represents the entitlement of agent i, that is, the amount of items to which i is entitled (out of the total of h). These entitlements are often normalized such that \sum_^n t_i = 1. Alternatively, they can be normalized such that their sum is h; in this case the entitlements are called ''quotas'' and termed denoted by q_i, where q_i := t_i\cdot h and \sum_^n q_i = h. Alternatively, one is given a vector of ''populations (p_1,\ldots,p_n)''; here, the entitlement of agent i is t_i = p_i / \sum_^n p_j.


Output

The output is a vector of integers a_1,\ldots,a_n with \sum_^n a_i = h, called an ''apportionment'' of h, where a_i is the number of items allocated to agent ''i''. For each party i, the real number q_i := t_i\cdot h is called the ''entitlement'' or ''seat quota'' for i, and denotes the exact number of items that should be given to i. In general, a "fair" apportionment is one in which each allocation a_i is as close as possible to the quota q_i. An apportionment method may return a set of apportionment vectors (in other words: it is a
multivalued function In mathematics, a multivalued function, multiple-valued function, many-valued function, or multifunction, is a function that has two or more values in its range for at least one point in its domain. It is a set-valued function with additional p ...
). This is required, since in some cases there is no fair way to distinguish between two possible solutions. For example, if h = 101 (or any other odd number) and t_1 = t_2 = 1/2, then (50,51) and (51,50) are both equally reasonable solutions, and there is no mathematical way to choose one over the other. While such ties are extremely rare in practice, the theory must account for them (in practice, when an apportionment method returns multiple outputs, one of them may be chosen by some external priority rules, or by
coin flipping Coin flipping, coin tossing, or heads or tails is using the thumb to make a coin go up while spinning in the air and checking which side is showing when it is down onto a surface, in order to randomly choose between two alternatives. It is a for ...
, but this is beyond the scope of the mathematical apportionment theory). An apportionment method is denoted by a multivalued function M(\mathbf, h); a particular M-solution is a single-valued function f(\mathbf, h) which selects a single apportionment from M(\mathbf, h). A partial apportionment method is an apportionment method for specific fixed values of n and h; it is a multivalued function M^*(\mathbf) that accepts only ''n''-vectors.


Variants

Sometimes, the input also contains a vector of integers r_1,\ldots,r_n representing ''minimum requirements - r_i'' represents the smallest number of items that agent i should receive, regardless of its entitlement. So there is an additional requirement on the output: a_i \geq r_i for all i. When the agents are political parties, these numbers are usually 0, so this vector is omitted. But when the agents are states or districts, these numbers are often positive in order to ensure that all are represented. They can be the same for all agents (e.g. 1 for USA states, 2 for France districts), or different (e.g. in Canada or the European parliament). Sometimes there is also a vector of ''maximum requirements'', but this is less common.


Basic requirements

There are basic properties that should be satisfied by any reasonable apportionment method. They were given different names by different authors: the names on the left are from Pukelsheim; The names in parentheses on the right are from Balinsky and Young. *
Anonymity Anonymity describes situations where the acting person's identity is unknown. Anonymity may be created unintentionally through the loss of identifying information due to the passage of time or a destructive event, or intentionally if a person cho ...
(=Symmetry) means that the apportionment does not depend on the agents' names or indices. Formally, if \mathbf is any permutation of \mathbf, then the apportionments in M(\mathbf, h) are exactly the corresponding permutations of the apportionments in M(\mathbf, h). **This requirement makes sense when there are no minimal requirements, or when the requirements are the same; if they are not the same, then anonymity should hold subject to the requirements being satisfied. * Balancedness (=Balance) means that if two agents have ''equal'' entitlements, then their allocation should differ by at most 1: t_i = t_j implies a_i \geq a_j-1. * Concordance (=Weak population monotonicity) means that an agent with a strictly ''higher'' entitlement receives at least as many items: t_i > t_j implies a_i \geq a_j. *Decency (=Homogeneity) means that scaling the entitlement vector does not change the outcome. Formally, M(c\cdot \mathbf, h) = M(\mathbf, h) for every constant ''c'' (this is automatically satisfied if the input to the apportionment method is normalized). *Exactness (=Weak proportionality) means that if there exists a perfect solution, then it must be selected. Formally, for normalized \mathbf, if the quota q_i = t_i\cdot h of each agent i is an integer number, then M(\mathbf, h) must contain a unique vector (q_1,\ldots,q_n). In other words, if an ''h''-apportionment \mathbf is exactly proportional to \mathbf, then it should be the unique element of M(\mathbf, h). **Strong exactness means that exactness also holds "in the limit". That is, if a sequence of entitlement vectors converges to an integer quota vector (q_1,\ldots,q_n), then the only allocation vector in all elements of the sequence is (q_1,\ldots,q_n). To see the difference from weak exactness, consider the following rule. (a) Give each agent its quota rounded down, \lfloor q_i\rfloor; (b) give the remaining seats iteratively to the largest parties. This rule is weakly exact, but not strongly exact. For example, suppose ''h''=6 and consider the sequence of quota vectors (4+1/''k'', 2-1/''k''). The above rule yields the allocation (5,1) for all ''k'', even though the limit when k→∞ is the integer vector (4,2). **Strong proportionality means that, in addition, if \mathbf\in M(\mathbf, h'), and h < h', and there is some ''h''-apportionment \mathbf that is exactly proportional to \mathbf', then it should be the unique element of M(\mathbf, h). For example, if one solution in M(\mathbf, 6) is (3,3), then the only solution in M(\mathbf, 4) must be (2,2). *Completeness means that, if some apportionment \mathbf is returned for a converging sequence of entitlement vectors, then \mathbf is also returned for their limit vector. In other words, the set \ - the set of entitlement vectors for which \mathbf is a possible apportionment - is topologically closed. An incomplete method can be "completed" by adding the apportionment \mathbf to any limit entitlement if and only if it belongs to every entitlement in the sequence. The completion of a symmetric and proportional apportionment method is complete, symmetric and proportional. **Completeness is violated by methods that apply an external tie-breaking rule, as done by many countries in practice. The tie-breaking rule applies only in the limit case, so it might break the completeness. **Completeness and weak-exactness together imply strong-exactness. If a complete and weakly-exact method is modified by adding an appropriate tie-breaking rule, then the resulting rule is no longer complete, but it is still strongly-exact.


Other considerations

The proportionality of apportionment can be measured by
seats-to-votes ratio The seats-to-votes ratio, also known as the advantage ratio, is a measure of equal representation of voters. The equation for seats-to-votes ratio for a political party ''i'' is: : \mathrm = s_i/v_i, where \mathrm is fraction of votes cast for t ...
and
Gallagher index The Gallagher index measures an electoral system's relative Proportional representation, disproportionality between votes received and seats in a legislature. As such, it measures the difference between the percentage of votes each party gets and ...
. The proportionality of apportionment together with
electoral threshold The electoral threshold, or election threshold, is the minimum share of votes that a candidate or political party requires before they become entitled to representation or additional seats in a legislature. This limit can operate in various ...
s impact political fragmentation and
barrier to entry In theories of competition in economics, a barrier to entry, or an economic barrier to entry, is a fixed cost that must be incurred by a new entrant, regardless of production or sales activities, into a market that incumbents do not have or hav ...
to the political competition.


Common apportionment methods

There are many apportionment methods, and they can be classified into several approaches. # Largest remainder methods start by computing the vector of quotas rounded down, that is, \lfloor q_1 \rfloor,\ldots,\lfloor q_n \rfloor. If the sum of these rounded values is exactly h, then this vector is returned as the unique apportionment. Typically, the sum is smaller than h. In this case, the remaining items are allocated among the agents according to their ''remainders q_i - \lfloor q_i \rfloor'': the agent with the largest remainder receives one seat, then the agent with the second-largest remainder receives one seat, and so on, until all items are allocated. There are several variants of the LR method, depending on which quota is used: #* The simple quota, also called the
Hare quota The Hare quota (sometimes called the simple, ideal, or Hamilton quota) is the number of voters represented by each legislator in an idealized system of proportional representation where every vote is used to elect someone. The Hare quota is eq ...
, is t_i h. Using LR with the Hare quota leads to Hamilton's method. #* The Hagenbach-Bischoff quota, also called the exact Droop quota, is t_i\cdot(h+1). The quotas in this method are larger, so there are fewer remaining items. In theory, it is possible that the sum of rounded-down quotas would be h+1 which is larger than h, but this rarely happens in practice. # Divisor methods, instead of using a fixed multiplier in the quota (such as h or h+1), choose the multiplier such that the sum of rounded quotas is exactly equal to h, so there are no remaining items to allocate. Formally, M(\mathbf,h) := \. Divisor methods differ by the method they use for rounding. A divisor method is parametrized by a ''divisor function'' d(k) which specifies, for each integer k\geq 0, a real number in the interval , k+1/math>. It means that all numbers in , d(k)/math> should be rounded down to k, and all numbers in (k), k+1/math> should be rounded up to k+1. The rounding function is denoted by \operatorname^d(x), and returns an integer k such that d(k-1)\leq x \leq d(k). The number d(k) itself can be rounded both up and down, so the rounding function is multi-valued. For example, Adams' method uses d(k) = k, which corresponds to rounding up; D'Hondt/Jefferson method uses d(k) = k+1, which corresponds to rounding down; and Webster/Sainte-Laguë method uses d(k) = k+0.5, which corresponds to rounding to the nearest integer. A divisor method can also be computed iteratively: initially, a_i is set to 0 for all parties. Then, at each iteration, the next seat is allocated to a party which maximizes the ratio \frac. # Rank-index methods are parametrized by a function r(t,a) which is decreasing in a. The apportionment is computed iteratively. Initially, set a_i to 0 for all parties. Then, at each iteration, allocate the next seat to an agent which maximizes r(t_i,a_i). Divisor methods are a special case of rank-index methods: a divisor method with divisor function d(a) is equivalent to a rank-index method with rank-index r(t,a) = t/d(a). # Optimization-based methods aim to attain, for each instance, an allocation that is "as fair as possible" for this instance. An allocation is "fair" if a_i = q_i for all agents ''i''; in this case, we say that the "unfairness" of the allocation is 0. If this equality is violated, one can define a measure of "total unfairness", and try to minimize it. One can minimize the ''sum'' of unfairness levels, or the ''maximum'' unfairness level. Each optimization criterion leads to a different optimal apportionment rule.


Staying within the quota

The ''exact quota'' of agent i is q_i = t_i\cdot h. A basic requirement from an apportionment method is that it allocates to each agent i its quota q_i if it is an integer; otherwise, it should allocate it an integer that is near the exact quota, that is, either its ''lower quota'' \lfloor q_i\rfloor or its ''upper quota'' \lceil q_i\rceil . We say that an apportionment method - * Satisfies lower quota if a_i\geq \lfloor q_i\rfloor for all i (this holds iff a_i + 1 > q_i ). * Satisfies upper quota if a_i\leq \lceil q_i\rceil for all i (this holds iff a_i - 1 < q_i ). *Satisfies both quotas if both the above conditions hold (this holds iff \frac < 1 < \frac ). Hamilton's largest-remainder method satisfies both lower quota and upper quota by construction. This does not hold for the divisor methods. * All divisor methods satisfy both quotas when there are 2 agents; *Webster's method is the only divisor method satisfying both quotas for 3 agents; *Adams' method is the only divisor method satisfying upper quota for any number of agents; * Jefferson's method is the only divisor method satisfying lower quota for any number of agents; *No divisor method simultaneously violates upper quota for one agent and violates lower quota for another agent. Therefore, no divisor method satisfies both upper quota and lower quota for any number of agents. The uniqueness of Jefferson and Adams holds even in the much larger class of rank-index methods. This can be seen as a disadvantage of divisor methods, but it can also be considered a disadvantage of the quota criterion:
"''For example, to give D 26 instead of 25 seats in Table 10.1 would mean taking a seat from one of the smaller states A, B, or C. Such a transfer would penalize the per capita representation of the small state much more - in both absolute and relative terms - than state D is penalized by getting one less than its lower quota. Similar examples can be invented in which some state might reasonably get more than its upper quota. It can be argued that staying within the quota is not really compatible with the idea of proportionality at all, since it allows a much greater variance in the per capita representation of smaller states than it does for larger states''."
In Monte-Carlo simulations, Webster's method satisfies both quotas with a very high probability. Moreover, Webster's method is the only division method that satisfies ''near quota'': there are no agents i, j such that moving a seat from i to j would bring both of them nearer to their quotas:
q_i-(a_i-1) ~<~ a_i - q_i ~~\text~~ (a_j+1)-q_j ~<~ q_j - a_j.
Jefferson's method can be modified to satisfy both quotas, yielding the Quota-Jefferson method. Moreover, ''any'' divisor method can be modified to satisfy both quotas. This yields the Quota-Webster method, Quota-Hill method, etc. This family of methods is often called the quatatone methods, as they satisfy both quotas and house-monotonicity.


Minimizing pairwise inequality

One way to evaluate apportionment methods is by whether they minimize the amount of ''inequality'' between pairs of agents. Clearly, inequality should take into account the different entitlements: if a_i/t_i = a_j / t_j then the agents are treated "equally" (w.r.t. to their entitlements); otherwise, if a_i/t_i > a_j / t_j then agent i is favored, and if a_i/t_i < a_j / t_j then agent j is favored. However, since there are 16 ways to rearrange the equality a_i/t_i = a_j / t_j, there are correspondingly many ways by which inequality can be defined. * , a_i/t_i - a_j / t_j, . Webster's method is the unique apportionment method in which, for each pair of agents i and j, this difference is minimized (that is, moving a seat from i to j or vice versa would not make the difference smaller). * a_i - (t_i/t_j)a_j for a_i/t_i \geq a_j/t_j This leads to Adams's method. * a_i(t_j/t_i) - a_j for a_i/t_i \geq a_j/t_j. This leads to Jefferson's method. * , t_i/a_i - t_j /a_j, . This leads to Dean's method. * \left, \frac - 1\. This leads to the Huntington-Hill method. This analysis was done by Huntington in the 1920s. Some of the possibilities do not lead to a stable solution. For example, if we define inequality as , a_i/a_j - t_i/t_j, , then there are instances in which, for any allocation, moving a seat from one agent to another might decrease their pairwise inequality. There is an example with 3 states with populations (737,534,329) and 16 seats.


Bias towards large/small agents

The ''
seat bias Seat bias is a property describing methods of apportionment. These are methods used to allocate seats in a parliament among federal states or among political parties. A method is ''biased'' if it systematically favors small parties over large par ...
'' of an apportionment is the tendency of an apportionment method to systematically favor either large or small parties. Jefferson's method and Droop's method are heavily biased in favor of large states; Adams' method is biased in favor of small states; and the Webster and Huntington–Hill methods are effectively unbiased toward either large or small states.


Consistency properties

Consistency properties are properties that characterize an apportionment ''method'', rather than a particular apportionment. Each consistency property compares the outcomes of a particular method on different inputs. Several such properties have been studied. State-population monotonicity means that, if the entitlement of an agent increases, its apportionment should not decrease. The name comes from the setting where the agents are federal states, whose entitlements are determined by their population. A violation of this property is called the '' population paradox''. There are several variants of this property. One variant - the ''pairwise PM'' - is satisfied exclusively by divisor methods. That is, an apportionment method is pairwise PM if-and-only-if it is a divisor method. When n\geq 4 and h\geq n +3, no partial apportionment method satisfies pairwise-PM, lower quota and upper quota. Combined with the previous statements, it implies that no divisor method satisfies both quotas. House monotonicity means that, when the total number of seats h increases, no agent loses a seat. The violation of this property is called the '' Alabama paradox''. It was considered particularly important in the early days of the USA, when the congress size increased every ten years. House-monotonicity is weaker than pairwise-PM. All rank-index methods (hence all divisor methods) are house-monotone - this clearly follows from the iterative procedure. Besides the divisor methods, there are other house-monotone methods, and some of them also satisfy both quotas. For example, the ''Quota method'' of Balinsky and Young satisfies house-monotonicity and upper-quota by construction, and it can be proved that it also satisfies lower-quota. It can be generalized: there is a general algorithm that yields ''all'' apportionment methods which are both house-monotone and satisfy both quotas. However, all these quota-based methods (Quota-Jefferson, Quota-Hill, etc.) may violate pairwise-PM: there are examples in which one agent gains in population but loses seats. Uniformity (also called
coherence Coherence is, in general, a state or situation in which all the parts or ideas fit together well so that they form a united whole. More specifically, coherence, coherency, or coherent may refer to the following: Physics * Coherence (physics ...
) means that, if we take some subset of the agents 1,\ldots,k, and apply the same method to their combined allocation h_k = a_1+\cdots+a_k, then the result is the vector (a_1,\ldots,a_k). All rank-index methods (hence all divisor methods) are uniform, since they assign seats to agents in a pre-determined method - determined by r(t,a), and this order does not depend on the presence or absence of other agents. Moreover, every uniform method that is also ''anonymous'' and '' balanced'' must be a rank-index method. Every uniform method that is also ''
anonymous Anonymous may refer to: * Anonymity, the state of an individual's identity, or personally identifiable information, being publicly unknown ** Anonymous work, a work of art or literature that has an unnamed or unknown creator or author * Anonym ...
'', ''weakly-exact'' and ''
concordant Concordance may refer to: * Agreement (linguistics), a form of cross-reference between different parts of a sentence or phrase * Bible concordance, an alphabetical listing of terms in the Bible * Concordant coastline, in geology, where beds, or la ...
'' (= t_i > t_j implies a_i \geq a_j) must be a divisor method. Moreover, among all anonymous methods: * Jefferson's method is the only uniform method satisfying lower quota; * Adams's method is the only uniform method satisfying upper quota; * Webster's method is the only uniform method that is near quota; * No uniform method satisfies both quotas. In particular, Hamilton's method and the Quota method are not uniform. However, the Quota method is the unique method that satisfies both quotas in addition to house-monotonicity and "quota-consistency", which is a weaker form of uniformity.


Encouraging coalitions

When the agents are political parties, they often split or merge. How such splitting/merging affects the apportionment will impact political fragmentation. Suppose a certain apportionment method gives two agents i,j some a_i, a_j seats respectively, and then these two agents form a coalition, and the method is re-activated. * An apportionment method ''always'' ''encourages coalitions'' if a coalition of two parties receives at least a_i + a_j seats (in other words, it is ''split-proof'' - a party cannot gain a seat by splitting). * An apportionment method ''always'' ''encourages schisms'' if the coalition receives at most a_i + a_j seats (in other words, it is ''merge-proof'' - two parties cannot gain a seat by merging). Among the divisor methods: * Jefferson's method is the unique split-proof divisor method; * Adams's method is the unique merge-proof divisor method; *Webster's method is neither split-proof nor merge-proof, but it is "coalition neutral": when votes are distributed randomly (with
uniform A uniform is a variety of costume worn by members of an organization while usually participating in that organization's activity. Modern uniforms are most often worn by armed forces and paramilitary organizations such as police, emergency serv ...
remainders), a coalition is equally likely to gain a seat or to lose a seat. Since these are different methods, no divisor method gives every coalition of ''i,j'' ''exactly'' a_i + a_j seats. Moreover, this uniqueness can be extended to the much larger class of rank-index methods. A weaker property, called "coalitional-stability", is that every coalition of ''i,j'' should receive between a_i + a_j-1 and a_i + a_j+1 seats; so a party can gain at most one seat by merging/splitting. * The Hamilton method is coalitionally-stable. * A divisor method with divisor d is coalitionally-stable iff d(a_1 + a_2) \leq d(a_1) + d(a_2) \leq d(a_1 + a_2+1); this holds for all five standard divisor methods. Moreover, every method satisfying both quotas is "almost coalitionally-stable" - it gives every coalition between a_i + a_j-2 and a_i + a_j+2 seats.


Summary table

The following table summarizes uniqueness results for classes of apportionment methods. For example, the top-left cell states that Jefferson's method is the unique divisor method satisfying the lower quota rule.


Implementations


Javascript demo of several common apportionment rules


See also

*
Proportional representation Proportional representation (PR) refers to any electoral system under which subgroups of an electorate are reflected proportionately in the elected body. The concept applies mainly to political divisions (Political party, political parties) amon ...
*
Proportional cake-cutting with different entitlements In the fair cake-cutting problem, the partners often have different entitlements. For example, the resource may belong to two shareholders such that Alice holds 8/13 and George holds 5/13. This leads to the criterion of ''weighted proportionality'' ...
*
Fair item allocation Fair item allocation is a kind of the fair division problem in which the items to divide are ''discrete'' rather than continuous. The items have to be divided among several partners who potentially value them differently, and each item has to be gi ...


Further reading

* – assigning some seats randomly. * * – Apportionment when there are errors in the population counts


References

{{Mathematics of Apportionment (politics) Mathematical theorems Apportionment method criteria