In
mathematics
Mathematics is a field of study that discovers and organizes methods, Mathematical theory, theories and theorems that are developed and Mathematical proof, proved for the needs of empirical sciences and mathematics itself. There are many ar ...
and
fair division
Fair division is the problem in game theory of dividing a set of resources among several people who have an Entitlement (fair division), entitlement to them so that each person receives their due share. The central tenet of fair division is that ...
, apportionment problems involve dividing (''apportioning'') a
whole number
An integer is the number zero ( 0), a positive natural number (1, 2, 3, ...), or the negation of a positive natural number ( −1, −2, −3, ...). The negations or additive inverses of the positive natural numbers are referred to as negative ...
of identical goods fairly across several parties with
real-valued
entitlements
An entitlement is a government program guaranteeing access to some benefit by members of a specific group and based on established rights or by legislation. A "right" is itself an entitlement associated with a moral or social principle, while an ...
. The original, and best-known, example of an apportionment problem involves distributing seats in a
legislature
A legislature (, ) is a deliberative assembly with the legal authority to make laws for a political entity such as a country, nation or city on behalf of the people therein. They are often contrasted with the executive and judicial power ...
between different
federal states or
political parties
A political party is an organization that coordinates candidates to compete in a particular area's elections. It is common for the members of a party to hold similar ideas about politics, and parties may promote specific ideological or p ...
. However, apportionment methods can be applied to other situations as well, including
bankruptcy problems,
inheritance law
Inheritance is the practice of receiving private property, titles, debts, entitlements, privileges, rights, and obligations upon the death of an individual. The rules of inheritance differ among societies and have changed over time. Offici ...
(e.g.
dividing animals),
manpower planning (e.g. demographic quotas), and rounding
percentages
In mathematics, a percentage () is a number or ratio expressed as a fraction of 100. It is often denoted using the ''percent sign'' (%), although the abbreviations ''pct.'', ''pct'', and sometimes ''pc'' are also used. A percentage is a dimen ...
.
Mathematically, an apportionment method is just a method of
rounding
Rounding or rounding off is the process of adjusting a number to an approximate, more convenient value, often with a shorter or simpler representation. For example, replacing $ with $, the fraction 312/937 with 1/3, or the expression √2 with ...
real numbers to natural numbers. Despite the simplicity of this problem, every method of rounding suffers one or more
paradoxes
A paradox is a logically self-contradictory statement or a statement that runs contrary to one's expectation. It is a statement that, despite apparently valid reasoning from true or apparently true premises, leads to a seemingly self-contradictor ...
, as proven by the
Balinski–Young theorem. The mathematical theory of apportionment identifies what properties can be expected from an apportionment method.
The mathematical theory of apportionment was studied as early as 1907 by the mathematician
Agner Krarup Erlang
Agner Krarup Erlang (1 January 1878 – 3 February 1929) was a Danish mathematician, statistician and engineer, who invented the fields of traffic engineering and queueing theory.
Erlang's 1909 paper, and subsequent papers over the decades, a ...
. It was later developed to a great detail by the mathematician
Michel Balinski
Michel Louis Balinski (born Michał Ludwik Baliński; October 6, 1933 – February 4, 2019) was an American and French applied mathematician, economist, operations research analyst and political scientist. Educated in the United States, from 198 ...
and the economist
Peyton Young
Hobart Peyton Young (born March 9, 1945) is an American game theorist and economist known for his contributions to evolutionary game theory and its application to the study of institutional and technological change, as well as the theory of lea ...
.
Definitions
Input
The inputs to an apportionment method are:
* A positive integer
representing the total number of items to allocate. It is also called the ''house size'', since in many cases, the items to allocate are seats in a house of representatives.
*A positive integer
representing the number of ''agents'' to which items should be allocated. For example, these can be
federal states or
political parties
A political party is an organization that coordinates candidates to compete in a particular area's elections. It is common for the members of a party to hold similar ideas about politics, and parties may promote specific ideological or p ...
.
* A vector of numbers
representing ''entitlements'' -
represents the
entitlement of agent
, that is, the amount of items to which
is entitled (out of the total of
). These entitlements are often normalized such that
. Alternatively, they can be normalized such that their sum is
; in this case the entitlements are called ''quotas'' and termed denoted by
, where
and
. Alternatively, one is given a vector of ''populations
''; here, the entitlement of agent
is
.
Output
The output is a vector of integers
with
, called an ''apportionment'' of
, where
is the number of items allocated to agent ''i''.
For each party
, the real number
is called the
''entitlement'' or ''seat quota'' for
, and denotes the exact number of items that should be given to
. In general, a "fair" apportionment is one in which each allocation
is as close as possible to the quota
.
An apportionment method may return a set of apportionment vectors (in other words: it is a
multivalued function
In mathematics, a multivalued function, multiple-valued function, many-valued function, or multifunction, is a function that has two or more values in its range for at least one point in its domain. It is a set-valued function with additional p ...
). This is required, since in some cases there is no fair way to distinguish between two possible solutions. For example, if
(or any other odd number) and
, then (50,51) and (51,50) are both equally reasonable solutions, and there is no mathematical way to choose one over the other. While such ties are extremely rare in practice, the theory must account for them (in practice, when an apportionment method returns multiple outputs, one of them may be chosen by some external priority rules, or by
coin flipping
Coin flipping, coin tossing, or heads or tails is using the thumb to make a coin go up while spinning in the air and checking which side is showing when it is down onto a surface, in order to randomly choose between two alternatives. It is a for ...
, but this is beyond the scope of the mathematical apportionment theory).
An apportionment method is denoted by a multivalued function
; a particular
-solution is a single-valued function
which selects a single apportionment from
.
A partial apportionment method is an apportionment method for specific fixed values of
and
; it is a multivalued function
that accepts only ''
''-vectors.
Variants
Sometimes, the input also contains a vector of integers
representing ''minimum requirements -
'' represents the smallest number of items that agent
should receive, regardless of its entitlement. So there is an additional requirement on the output:
for all
.
When the agents are political parties, these numbers are usually 0, so this vector is omitted. But when the agents are states or districts, these numbers are often positive in order to ensure that all are represented. They can be the same for all agents (e.g. 1 for USA states, 2 for France districts), or different (e.g. in Canada or the European parliament).
Sometimes there is also a vector of ''maximum requirements'', but this is less common.
Basic requirements
There are basic properties that should be satisfied by any reasonable apportionment method. They were given different names by different authors: the names on the left are from Pukelsheim;
The names in parentheses on the right are from Balinsky and Young.
*
Anonymity
Anonymity describes situations where the acting person's identity is unknown. Anonymity may be created unintentionally through the loss of identifying information due to the passage of time or a destructive event, or intentionally if a person cho ...
(=Symmetry) means that the apportionment does not depend on the agents' names or indices. Formally, if
is any permutation of
, then the apportionments in
are exactly the corresponding permutations of the apportionments in
.
**This requirement makes sense when there are no minimal requirements, or when the requirements are the same; if they are not the same, then anonymity should hold subject to the requirements being satisfied.
*
Balancedness (=Balance) means that if two agents have ''equal'' entitlements, then their allocation should differ by at most 1:
implies
.
*
Concordance (=Weak population monotonicity) means that an agent with a strictly ''higher'' entitlement receives at least as many items:
implies
.
*Decency (=Homogeneity) means that scaling the entitlement vector does not change the outcome. Formally,
for every constant ''c'' (this is automatically satisfied if the input to the apportionment method is normalized).
*Exactness (=Weak proportionality) means that if there exists a perfect solution, then it must be selected. Formally, for normalized
, if the quota
of each agent
is an integer number, then
must contain a unique vector
. In other words, if an ''h''-apportionment
is exactly proportional to
, then it should be the unique element of
.
**Strong exactness
means that exactness also holds "in the limit". That is, if a sequence of entitlement vectors converges to an integer quota vector
, then the only allocation vector in all elements of the sequence is
. To see the difference from weak exactness, consider the following rule. (a) Give each agent its quota rounded down,
; (b) give the remaining seats iteratively to the largest parties. This rule is weakly exact, but not strongly exact. For example, suppose ''h''=6 and consider the sequence of quota vectors (4+1/''k'', 2-1/''k''). The above rule yields the allocation (5,1) for all ''k'', even though the limit when k→∞ is the integer vector (4,2).
**Strong proportionality
means that, in addition, if
, and
, and there is some ''h''-apportionment
that is exactly proportional to
, then it should be the unique element of
. For example, if one solution in
is (3,3), then the only solution in
must be (2,2).
*Completeness means that, if some apportionment
is returned for a converging sequence of entitlement vectors, then
is also returned for their limit vector. In other words, the set
- the set of entitlement vectors for which
is a possible apportionment - is
topologically closed. An incomplete method can be "completed" by adding the apportionment
to any limit entitlement if and only if it belongs to every entitlement in the sequence. The completion of a symmetric and proportional apportionment method is complete, symmetric and proportional.
**Completeness is violated by methods that apply an external tie-breaking rule, as done by many countries in practice. The tie-breaking rule applies only in the limit case, so it might break the completeness.
**Completeness and weak-exactness together imply strong-exactness. If a complete and weakly-exact method is modified by adding an appropriate tie-breaking rule, then the resulting rule is no longer complete, but it is still strongly-exact.
Other considerations
The proportionality of apportionment can be measured by
seats-to-votes ratio
The seats-to-votes ratio, also known as the advantage ratio, is a measure of equal representation of voters. The equation for seats-to-votes ratio for a political party ''i'' is:
: \mathrm = s_i/v_i,
where \mathrm is fraction of votes cast for t ...
and
Gallagher index
The Gallagher index measures an electoral system's relative Proportional representation, disproportionality between votes received and seats in a legislature. As such, it measures the difference between the percentage of votes each party gets and ...
. The proportionality of apportionment together with
electoral threshold
The electoral threshold, or election threshold, is the minimum share of votes that a candidate or political party requires before they become entitled to representation or additional seats in a legislature.
This limit can operate in various ...
s impact
political fragmentation and
barrier to entry
In theories of competition in economics, a barrier to entry, or an economic barrier to entry, is a fixed cost that must be incurred by a new entrant, regardless of production or sales activities, into a market that incumbents do not have or hav ...
to the political competition.
Common apportionment methods
There are many apportionment methods, and they can be classified into several approaches.
#
Largest remainder methods start by computing the vector of quotas rounded down, that is,
. If the sum of these rounded values is exactly
, then this vector is returned as the unique apportionment. Typically, the sum is smaller than
. In this case, the remaining items are allocated among the agents according to their ''remainders
'': the agent with the largest remainder receives one seat, then the agent with the second-largest remainder receives one seat, and so on, until all items are allocated. There are several variants of the LR method, depending on which quota is used:
#* The simple quota, also called the
Hare quota
The Hare quota (sometimes called the simple, ideal, or Hamilton quota) is the number of voters represented by each legislator in an idealized system of proportional representation where every vote is used to elect someone. The Hare quota is eq ...
, is
. Using LR with the Hare quota leads to
Hamilton's method.
#* The
Hagenbach-Bischoff quota, also called the exact Droop quota, is
. The quotas in this method are larger, so there are fewer remaining items. In theory, it is possible that the sum of rounded-down quotas would be
which is larger than
, but this rarely happens in practice.
#
Divisor methods, instead of using a fixed multiplier in the quota (such as
or
), choose the multiplier such that the sum of rounded quotas is exactly equal to
, so there are no remaining items to allocate. Formally,
Divisor methods differ by the method they use for rounding. A divisor method is parametrized by a ''divisor function''
which specifies, for each integer
, a real number in the interval