The majority criterion is a
voting system criterion applicable to voting rules over ordinal preferences required that if only one candidate is ranked first by over 50% of voters, that candidate must win.
Some methods that comply with this criterion include any
Condorcet method
A Condorcet method (; ) is an election method that elects the candidate who wins a majority of the vote in every head-to-head election against each of the other candidates, whenever there is such a candidate. A candidate with this property, the ...
,
instant-runoff voting
Instant-runoff voting (IRV; ranked-choice voting (RCV), preferential voting, alternative vote) is a single-winner ranked voting election system where Sequential loser method, one or more eliminations are used to simulate Runoff (election), ...
,
Bucklin voting
Bucklin voting is a class of voting methods that can be used for single-member and multi-member districts. As in highest median rules like the majority judgment, the Bucklin winner will be one of the candidates with the highest median ranking ...
,
plurality voting
Plurality voting refers to electoral systems in which the candidates in an electoral district who poll more than any other (that is, receive a plurality) are elected.
Under single-winner plurality voting, and in systems based on single-member ...
, and
approval voting
Approval voting is a single-winner rated voting system where voters can approve of all the candidates as they like instead of Plurality voting, choosing one. The method is designed to eliminate vote-splitting while keeping election administration ...
.
The
mutual majority criterion
The mutual majority criterion is a criterion for evaluating electoral systems. It is also known as the majority criterion for solid coalitions and the generalized majority criterion. This criterion requires that whenever a majority of voters prefe ...
is a generalized form of the criterion meant to account for when the majority prefers multiple candidates above all others; voting methods which pass majority but fail mutual majority can encourage all but one of the majority's preferred candidates to drop out in order to ensure one of the majority-preferred candidates wins, creating a
spoiler effect
In social choice theory and politics, a spoiler effect happens when a losing candidate affects the results of an election simply by participating. Voting rules that are not affected by spoilers are said to be spoilerproof.
The frequency and se ...
.
Difference from the Condorcet criterion
By the majority criterion, a candidate ''C'' should win if a majority of voters answers affirmatively to the question "Do you (strictly) prefer ''C'' to every other candidate?"
The
Condorcet criterion
A Condorcet winner (, ) is a candidate who would receive the support of more than half of the electorate in a one-on-one race against any one of their opponents. Voting systems where a majority winner will always win are said to satisfy the Condo ...
gives a stronger and more intuitive notion of majoritarianism (and as such is sometimes referred to as
majority rule
In social choice theory, the majority rule (MR) is a social choice rule which says that, when comparing two options (such as bills or candidates), the option preferred by more than half of the voters (a ''majority'') should win.
In political ...
). According to it, a candidate ''C'' should win if for every other candidate ''Y'' there is a majority of voters that answers affirmatively to the question "Do you prefer ''C'' to ''Y''?" A Condorcet system necessarily satisfies the majority criterion, but not vice versa.
A Condorcet winner ''C'' only has to defeat every other candidate "one-on-one"—in other words, when comparing ''C'' to any ''specific'' alternative. To be the majority choice of the electorate, a candidate ''C'' must be able to defeat every other candidate ''simultaneously—''i.e. voters who are asked to choose between ''C'' and "anyone else" must pick "''C''" instead of ''any'' other candidate.
Equivalently, a Condorcet winner can have several different majority coalitions supporting them in each one-on-one matchup. A majority winner must instead have a ''single'' (consistent) majority that supports them across all one-on-one matchups.
Application to cardinal voting methods
In systems with absolute rating categories such as
score SCORE may refer to:
*SCORE (software), a music scorewriter program
* SCORE (television), a weekend sports service of the defunct Financial News Network
*SCORE! Educational Centers
*SCORE International, an offroad racing organization
*Sarawak Corrido ...
and
highest median methods, it is not clear how the majority criterion should be defined. There are three notable definitions of for a candidate ''A'':
# If a majority of voters have (only) ''A'' receiving a higher score than any other candidate (even if this is not the highest possible score), this candidate will be elected.
# If (only) ''A'' receives a perfect score from more than half of all voters, this candidate will be elected.
# If a majority of voters prefer (only) ''A'' to any other candidate, they can choose to elect candidate ''A'' by strategizing.
The first criterion is not satisfied by any common cardinal voting method. Ordinal ballots can only tell us ''whether'' ''A'' is preferred to ''B'' (not ''by how much'' ''A'' is preferred to ''B''), and so if we only know most voters prefer ''A'' to ''B'', it is reasonable to say the majority should win. However, with cardinal voting systems, there is more information available, as voters also state the strength of their preferences. Thus in cardinal voting systems a sufficiently-motivated minority can sometimes outweigh the voices of a majority, if they would be strongly harmed by a policy or candidate.
Examples
Approval voting
Approval voting non trivially satisfies the ranked majority criterion, because it satisfies IIA.
Plurality voting
Any candidate receiving more than 50% of the vote will be elected by plurality.
Instant runoff
Instant-runoff voting satisfies majority--if a candidate is rated first by 50% of the electorate, they will win in the first round.
Borda count
For example 100 voters cast the following votes:
A has 110 Borda points (55 × 2 + 35 × 0 + 10 × 0). B has 135 Borda points (55 × 1 + 35 × 2 + 10 × 1). C has 55 Borda points (55 × 0 + 35 × 1 + 10 × 2).
Candidate A is the first choice of a majority of voters but candidate B wins the election.
Condorcet methods
Any
Condorcet method
A Condorcet method (; ) is an election method that elects the candidate who wins a majority of the vote in every head-to-head election against each of the other candidates, whenever there is such a candidate. A candidate with this property, the ...
will automatically satisfy the majority criterion.
Cardinal methods
Score voting
For example 100 voters cast the following votes:
Candidate B would win with a total of 80 × 9 + 20 × 10 = 720 + 200 = 920 rating points, versus 800 for candidate A.
Because candidate A is rated higher than candidate B by a (substantial) majority of the voters, but B is declared winner, this voting system fails to satisfy the criterion due to using additional information about the voters' opinion. Conversely, if the bloc of voters who rate A highest know they are in the majority, such as from pre-election polls, they can strategically give a maximal rating to A, a minimal rating to all others, and thereby guarantee the election of their favorite candidate. In this regard, if there exists a majority coalition, the coalition will have the ability to coordinate and elect their favorite candidate.
STAR voting
STAR voting fails majority, but satisfies the
majority loser criterion
The majority loser criterion is a criterion to evaluate single-winner voting systems. The criterion states that if a majority of voters give a candidate no support, i.e. do not list that candidate on their ballot, that candidate must lose (unles ...
.
Highest medians
It is controversial how to interpret the term "prefer" in the definition of the criterion. If majority support is interpreted in a relative sense, with a majority rating a preferred candidate above any other, the method does not pass, even with only two candidates. If the word "prefer" is interpreted in an absolute sense, as rating the preferred candidate with the highest available rating, then it does.
= Criterion 1
=
If "''A'' is preferred" means that the voter gives a better grade to ''A'' than to every other candidate, majority judgment can fail catastrophically. Consider the case below when is large:
''A'' is preferred by a majority, but ''B''s median is Good and ''A''s median is only Fair, so ''B'' would win. In fact, ''A'' can be preferred by up to (but not including) 100% of all voters, an exceptionally severe violation of the criterion.
= Criterion 2
=
If we define the majority criterion as requiring a voter to uniquely top-rate candidate ''A'', then this system passes the criterion; any candidate who receives the highest grade from a majority of voters receives the highest grade (and so can only be defeated by another candidate who has majority support).
See also
*
Mutual majority criterion
The mutual majority criterion is a criterion for evaluating electoral systems. It is also known as the majority criterion for solid coalitions and the generalized majority criterion. This criterion requires that whenever a majority of voters prefe ...
*
Voting system
An electoral or voting system is a set of rules used to determine the results of an election. Electoral systems are used in politics to elect governments, while non-political elections may take place in business, nonprofit organizations and inf ...
*
Voting system criterion
*
Condorcet criterion
A Condorcet winner (, ) is a candidate who would receive the support of more than half of the electorate in a one-on-one race against any one of their opponents. Voting systems where a majority winner will always win are said to satisfy the Condo ...
References
{{voting systems
Electoral system criteria