History
The loanable funds doctrine was formulated in the 1930s by British economist Dennis Robertson and Swedish economist Bertil Ohlin. However, Ohlin attributed its origin to Swedish economistBasic features
The loanable funds doctrine extends the classical theory, which determined the interest rate solely by saving and investment, in that it adds bank credit. The total amount of credit available in an economy can exceed private saving because the bank system is in a position to create credit out of thin air. Hence, the equilibrium (or market) interest rate is not only influenced by the propensities to save and invest but also by the creation or destruction of fiat money and credit. If the bank system enhances credit, it will at least temporarily diminish the market interest rate below the ''natural rate''. Wicksell had defined the natural rate as that interest rate which is compatible with a stable price level. Credit creation and credit destruction induce changes in the price level and in the level of economic activity. This is referred to as Wicksell's cumulative process. According to Ohlin (op. cit., p. 222), one cannot say "that the rate of interest equalises planned savings and planned investment, for it obviously does not do that. How, then, is the height of the interest rate determined. The answer is that the rate of interest is simply the price of credit, and that it is therefore governed by the supply of and demand for credit. The banking system – through its ability to give credit – ''can'' influence, and to some extent does affect, the interest level." In formal terms, the loanable funds doctrine determines the market interest rate through the following equilibrium condition: : where denote the price level, real saving, and real investment, respectively, while denotes changes in bank credit. Saving and investment are multiplied by the price level in order to obtain monetary variables, because credit comes also in monetary terms. In a fiat money system, bank credit creation equals money creation, Therefore, it is also common to represent the loanable funds doctrine as The preceding description holds for closed economies. In open economies, net capital outflows must be added to credit demand.Comparison with classical and Keynesian approaches
In classical theory, the interest rate ''i'' is determined by saving and investment alone: Changes in the quantity of money do not affect the interest rate but only influence the price level (as per theAmbiguous use
While the scholarly literature uses the term ''loanable funds doctrine'' in the sense defined above, textbook authorsMankiw, N. G. (2013) ''Macroeconomics''. Eighth edition: Macmillan, p. 68. and bloggers sometimes refer colloquially to "loanable funds" in connection with ''classical'' interest theory. This ambiguous use disregards the characteristic feature of the loanable funds doctrine, namely, its integration of bank credit into the theory of interest rate determination.References
{{Portal, Economics Macroeconomic theories Interest rates