Increasing Returns To Scale
   HOME

TheInfoList



OR:

In
economics Economics () is a behavioral science that studies the Production (economics), production, distribution (economics), distribution, and Consumption (economics), consumption of goods and services. Economics focuses on the behaviour and interac ...
, the concept of returns to scale arises in the context of a firm's
production function In economics, a production function gives the technological relation between quantities of physical inputs and quantities of output of goods. The production function is one of the key concepts of mainstream economics, mainstream neoclassical econ ...
. It explains the long-run linkage of increase in output (production) relative to associated increases in the inputs (
factors of production In economics, factors of production, resources, or inputs are what is used in the production process to produce output—that is, goods and services. The utilised amounts of the various inputs determine the quantity of output according to the rela ...
). In the long run, all factors of production are variable and subject to change in response to a given increase in production scale. In other words, returns to scale analysis is a long-term theory because a company can only change the scale of production in the long run by changing factors of production, such as building new facilities, investing in new machinery, or improving technology. There are three possible types of returns to scale: * If output increases by the same proportional change as all inputs change then there are constant returns to scale (CRS). For example, when inputs (labor and capital) increase by 100%, output increases by 100%. * If output increases by less than the proportional change in all inputs, there are decreasing returns to scale (DRS). For example, when inputs (labor and capital) increase by 100%, the increase in output is less than 100%. The main reason for the decreasing returns to scale is the increased management difficulties associated with the increased scale of production, the lack of coordination in all stages of production, and the resulting decrease in production efficiency. * If output increases by more than the proportional change in all inputs, there are increasing returns to scale (IRS). For example, when inputs (labor and capital) increase by 100%, the increase in output is greater than 100%. The main reason for the increasing returns to scale is the increase in production efficiency due to the expansion of the firm's production scale. A firm's production function could exhibit different types of returns to scale in different ranges of output. Typically, there could be increasing returns at relatively low output levels, decreasing returns at relatively high output levels, and constant returns at some range of output levels between those extremes. In mainstream microeconomics, the returns to scale faced by a firm are purely technologically imposed and are not influenced by economic decisions or by market conditions (i.e., conclusions about returns to scale are derived from the specific mathematical structure of the production function ''in isolation''). As production scales up, companies can use more advanced and sophisticated technologies, resulting in more streamlined and specialised production within the company.


Example

When the usages of all inputs increase by a factor of 2, new values for output will be: * Twice the previous output if there are constant returns to scale (CRS) * Less than twice the previous output if there are decreasing returns to scale (DRS) * More than twice the previous output if there are increasing returns to scale (IRS) Assuming that the factor costs are constant (that is, that the firm is a perfect competitor in all input markets) and the production function is homothetic, a firm experiencing constant returns will have constant long-run average costs, a firm experiencing decreasing returns will have increasing long-run average costs, and a firm experiencing increasing returns will have decreasing long-run average costs. However, this relationship breaks down if the firm does not face perfectly competitive factor markets (i.e., in this context, the price one pays for a good does depend on the amount purchased). For example, if there are increasing returns to scale in some range of output levels, but the firm is so big in one or more input markets that increasing its purchases of an input drives up the input's per-unit cost, then the firm could have diseconomies of scale in that range of output levels. Conversely, if the firm is able to get bulk discounts of an input, then it could have economies of scale in some range of output levels even if it has decreasing returns in production in that output range.


Formal definitions

Formally, a production function \ F(K,L) is defined to have: * Constant returns to scale if (for any constant ''a'' greater than 0): \ F(aK,aL)=aF(K,L) . In this case, the function F is
homogeneous Homogeneity and heterogeneity are concepts relating to the uniformity of a substance, process or image. A homogeneous feature is uniform in composition or character (i.e., color, shape, size, weight, height, distribution, texture, language, i ...
of degree 1. * Decreasing returns to scale if (for any constant ''a'' greater than 1): \ F(aK,aL) * Increasing returns to scale if (for any constant ''a'' greater than 1): \ F(aK,aL)>aF(K,L) where ''K'' and ''L'' are factors of production—capital and labor, respectively. In a more general set-up, for a multi-input-multi-output production processes, one may assume technology can be represented via some technology set, call it \ T , which must satisfy some regularity conditions of production theory. In this case, the property of constant returns to scale is equivalent to saying that technology set \ T is a cone, i.e., satisfies the property \ aT=T, \forall a>0 . In turn, if there is a production function that will describe the technology set \ T it will have to be homogeneous of degree 1.


Formal example

If the Cobb–Douglas production function has its general form :\ F(K,L)=AK^L^ with 0 and 0 then :\ F(aK,aL)=A(aK)^(aL)^=Aa^a^K^L^=a^AK^L^=a^F(K,L), and, for ''a'' > 1, there are increasing returns if ''b'' + ''c'' > 1, constant returns if ''b'' + ''c'' = 1, and decreasing returns if ''b'' + ''c'' < 1.


See also

*
Diseconomies of scale In microeconomics, diseconomies of scale are the cost disadvantages that economic actors accrue due to an increase in organizational size or in output, resulting in production of Product (business), goods and Service (economics), services at incre ...
and
Economies of scale In microeconomics, economies of scale are the cost advantages that enterprises obtain due to their scale of operation, and are typically measured by the amount of Productivity, output produced per unit of cost (production cost). A decrease in ...
*
Economies of agglomeration One of the major subfields of urban economics, economies of agglomeration (or agglomeration effects), explains, in broad terms, how urban agglomeration occurs in locations where cost savings can naturally arise. This term is most often discu ...
*
Economies of scope Economies of scope are "efficiencies formed by variety, not volume" (the latter concept is "economies of scale"). In the field of economics, "economies" is synonymous with cost savings and "scope" is synonymous with broadening production/service ...
*
Experience curve effects In industry, models of the learning or experience curve effect express the relationship between experience producing a good and the efficiency of that production, specifically, efficiency gains that follow investment in the effort. The effect ha ...
* Ideal firm size *
Homogeneous function In mathematics, a homogeneous function is a function of several variables such that the following holds: If each of the function's arguments is multiplied by the same scalar (mathematics), scalar, then the function's value is multiplied by some p ...
* Mohring effect *
Moore's law Moore's law is the observation that the Transistor count, number of transistors in an integrated circuit (IC) doubles about every two years. Moore's law is an observation and Forecasting, projection of a historical trend. Rather than a law of ...


References


Further reading

* Susanto Basu (2008). "Returns to scale measurement", '' The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics'', 2nd Edition
Abstract.
* James M. Buchanan and Yong J. Yoon, ed. (1994) ''The Return to Increasing Returns''. U.Mich. Press. Chapter-previe
links.
* John Eatwell (1987). "Returns to scale", '' The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics'', v. 4, pp. 165–66. * Färe, R., S. Grosskopf and C.A.K. Lovell (1986),
Scale economies and duality
Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie 46:2, pp. 175–182. . * Hanoch, G. (1975)
The elasticity of scale and the shape of average costs
, ''American Economic Review'' 65, pp. 492–497. * Panzar, J.C. and R.D. Willig (1977)
Economies of scale in multi-output production
, ''Quarterly Journal of Economics'' 91, 481-493. * Joaquim Silvestre (1987). "Economies and diseconomies of scale", ''The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics'', v. 2, pp. 80–84. * Spirros Vassilakis (1987). "Increasing returns to scale", ''The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics'', v. 2, pp. 761–64. *
Zelenyuk V. (2014) "Scale efficiency and homotheticity: equivalence of primal and dual measures", ''Journal of Productivity Analysis'' 42:1, pp 15-24.
.


External links

* * {{Authority control Production economics