In
consumer theory
The theory of consumer choice is the branch of microeconomics that relates preferences to consumption expenditures and to consumer demand curves. It analyzes how consumers maximize the desirability of their consumption as measured by their pre ...
, a consumer's preferences are called homothetic if they can be represented by a
utility function
As a topic of economics, utility is used to model worth or value. Its usage has evolved significantly over time. The term was introduced initially as a measure of pleasure or happiness as part of the theory of utilitarianism by moral philosoph ...
which is
homogeneous
Homogeneity and heterogeneity are concepts often used in the sciences and statistics relating to the uniformity of a substance or organism. A material or image that is homogeneous is uniform in composition or character (i.e. color, shape, siz ...
of degree 1.
For example, in an economy with two goods
, homothetic preferences can be represented by a utility function
that has the following property: for every
:
::
In
mathematics, a homothetic function is a
monotonic transformation of a function which is
homogeneous
Homogeneity and heterogeneity are concepts often used in the sciences and statistics relating to the uniformity of a substance or organism. A material or image that is homogeneous is uniform in composition or character (i.e. color, shape, siz ...
;
however, since
ordinal utility In economics, an ordinal utility function is a function representing the preferences of an agent on an ordinal scale. Ordinal utility theory claims that it is only meaningful to ask which option is better than the other, but it is meaningless to ask ...
functions are only defined up to an increasing
monotonic transformation, there is a small distinction between the two concepts in consumer theory.
In a model where competitive consumers optimize homothetic utility functions subject to a
budget constraint
In economics, a budget constraint represents all the combinations of goods and services that a consumer may purchase given current prices within his or her given income. Consumer theory uses the concepts of a budget constraint and a preference ...
, the ratios of goods demanded by consumers will depend only on
relative price
A relative price is the price of a commodity such as a good or service in terms of another; i.e., the ratio of two prices. A relative price may be expressed in terms of a ratio between the prices of any two goods or the ratio between the price o ...
s, not on
income
Income is the consumption and saving opportunity gained by an entity within a specified timeframe, which is generally expressed in monetary terms. Income is difficult to define conceptually and the definition may be different across fields. F ...
or scale. This translates to a linear
expansion path
In economics, an expansion path (also called a scale lineJain, TR; Khanna OP (2008). ''Economics.'' VK Publications, ) is a path connecting optimal input combinations as the scale of production expands.Hirschey, Mark (2008). ''Managerial econom ...
in income: the slope of indifference curves is constant along rays beginning at the origin.
This is to say, the
Engel curve
In microeconomics, an Engel curve describes how household expenditure on a particular good or service varies with household income. There are two varieties of Engel curves. Budget share Engel curves describe how the proportion of household income ...
for each good is linear.
Furthermore, the
indirect utility function
__NOTOC__
In economics, a consumer's indirect utility function
v(p, w) gives the consumer's maximal attainable utility when faced with a vector p of goods prices and an amount of income w. It reflects both the consumer's preferences and market con ...
can be written as a linear function of wealth
:
::
which is a special case of the
Gorman polar form Gorman polar form is a functional form for indirect utility functions in economics.
Motivation
Standard consumer theory is developed for a single consumer. The consumer has a utility function, from which his demand curves can be calculated. Then ...
. Hence, if all consumers have homothetic preferences (with the same coefficient on the wealth term), aggregate demand can be calculated by considering a single "representative consumer" who has the same preferences and the same aggregate income.
Examples
Utility functions having
constant elasticity of substitution
Constant elasticity of substitution (CES), in economics, is a property of some production functions and utility functions. Several economists have featured in the topic and have contributed in the final finding of the constant. They include Tom ...
(CES) are homothetic. They can be represented by a utility function such as:
:
This function is homogeneous of degree 1:
:
Linear utilities In economics and consumer theory, a linear utility function is a function of the form:
::u(x_1,x_2,\dots,x_m) = w_1 x_1 + w_2 x_2 + \dots w_m x_m
or, in vector form:
::u(\overrightarrow) = \overrightarrow \cdot \overrightarrow
where:
* m is the n ...
,
Leontief utilities In economics, especially in consumer theory, a Leontief utility function is a function of the form:
u(x_1,\ldots,x_m)=\min\left\ .
where:
* m is the number of different goods in the economy.
* x_i (for i\in 1,\dots,m) is the amount of good i in the ...
and
Cobb–Douglas utilities are special cases of CES functions and thus are also homothetic.
On the other hand,
quasilinear utilities
In economics and consumer theory, quasilinear utility functions are linear in one argument, generally the numeraire. Quasilinear preferences can be represented by the utility function u(x_1, x_2, \ldots, x_n) = x_1 + \theta (x_2, \ldots, x_n) whe ...
are not always homothetic. E.g, the function
cannot be represented as a homogeneous function.
Intratemporally vs. intertemporally homothetic preferences
Preferences are intratemporally homothetic if, in the same time period, consumers with different incomes but facing the same prices and having identical preferences will demand goods in the same proportions.
Preferences are intertemporally homothetic if, across time periods, rich and poor decision makers are equally averse to proportional fluctuations in consumption.
Models of modern
macroeconomics and public finance often assume the constant-relative-risk-aversion form for within period utility (also called the power utility or
isoelastic utility
In economics, the isoelastic function for utility, also known as the isoelastic utility function, or power utility function, is used to express utility in terms of consumption or some other economic variable that a decision-maker is concerned wit ...
). The reason is that, in combination with additivity over time, this gives homothetic intertemporal preferences and this homotheticity is of considerable analytic convenience (for example, it allows for the analysis of steady states in growth models). These assumptions imply that the
elasticity of intertemporal substitution Elasticity of intertemporal substitution (or intertemporal elasticity of substitution, EIS, IES) is a measure of responsiveness of the growth rate of consumption to the real interest rate. If the real interest rate rises, current consumption may d ...
, and its inverse,
the coefficient of (risk) aversion, are constant.
Evidence
However, it is well known that in reality, consumption patterns change with economic affluence. This means that preferences are not actually homothetic. It has long been established that relative price changes affect people differently even if all face the same set of prices.
See also
*
Homothetic transformation
In mathematics, a homothety (or homothecy, or homogeneous dilation) is a transformation of an affine space determined by a point ''S'' called its ''center'' and a nonzero number ''k'' called its ''ratio'', which sends point X to a point X' by t ...
*
Homogeneous function
In mathematics, a homogeneous function is a function of several variables such that, if all its arguments are multiplied by a scalar, then its value is multiplied by some power of this scalar, called the degree of homogeneity, or simply the '' ...
References
{{DEFAULTSORT:Homothetic Preferences
Utility function types