Milton Friedman
Milton Friedman (; July 31, 1912 – November 16, 2006) was an American economist and statistician who received the 1976 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences for his research on consumption analysis, monetary history and theory and ...
's book ''Essays in Positive Economics'' (1953) is a collection of earlier articles by the author with as its lead an original essay "The
Methodology
In its most common sense, methodology is the study of research methods. However, the term can also refer to the methods themselves or to the philosophical discussion of associated background assumptions. A method is a structured procedure for bri ...
of Positive Economics." This essay posits Friedman's famous, but controversial, principle (called the F-Twist by
Samuelson) that assumptions need not be "realistic" to serve as scientific hypotheses; they merely need to make significant predictions.
Contents of the book
The book is organized in four parts:
* Introduction
: The Methodology of Positive Economics
* Price Theory
: The Marshallian Demand Curve
: The ‘Welfare’ Effects of an Income Tax and an Excise Tax
* Monetary Theory and Policy
: The Effects of a Full-Employment Policy on Economic Stability: A Formal Analysis
: A Monetary and Fiscal Framework for Economic Stability
: The Case for Flexible Exchange Rates
: Commodity-Reserve Currency
: Discussion of the Inflationary Gap
: Comments on Monetary Policy
* Comments on Method
: Lange on Price Flexibility and Employment – A Methodological Criticism
: Lerner on the Economics of Control
The Methodology of Positive Economics
This first essay in the book explores
John Neville Keynes's distinction between
''positive'' and ''normative'' economics, what ''is'' vs. what ''ought to be'' in economic matters. The essay sets out an
epistemological
Epistemology is the branch of philosophy that examines the nature, origin, and limits of knowledge. Also called "the theory of knowledge", it explores different types of knowledge, such as propositional knowledge about facts, practical knowled ...
program for Friedman's own research.
The essay argues that economics as ''science'' should be free of normative judgments for it to be respected as objective and to inform normative economics (for example whether to raise the
minimum wage
A minimum wage is the lowest remuneration that employers can legally pay their employees—the price floor below which employees may not sell their labor. List of countries by minimum wage, Most countries had introduced minimum wage legislation b ...
). Normative judgments frequently involve implicit ''predictions'' about the consequences of different policies. The essay suggests that such differences in principle could be narrowed by progress in positive economics (1953, p. 5).
The essay argues that a useful economic theory should ''not'' be judged primarily by its
tautological completeness, however important in providing a consistent system for classifying elements of the theory and validly deriving implications therefrom. Rather a theory (or hypothesis) must be judged by its:
* ''simplicity'' in being able to predict at least as much as an alternate theory, although requiring less information
* ''fruitfulness'' in the precision and scope of its predictions and in its ability to generate additional research lines (p. 10).
In a famous and controversial passage, Friedman writes that:
:Truly important and significant hypotheses will be found to have "assumptions" that are wildly inaccurate descriptive representations of reality, and, in general, the more significant the theory, the more unrealistic the assumptions (in this sense) (p. 14).
This is because such hypotheses and descriptions extract only those crucial elements sufficient to yield relatively precise, valid predictions, omitting a welter of predictively irrelevant details. Of course descriptive unrealism by itself does not ensure a "significant theory" (pp. 14–15).
From such Friedman rejects testing a theory by the realism of its assumptions. Rather simplicity and fruitfulness incline toward such assumptions and postulates as
utility maximization
Utility maximization was first developed by utilitarian philosophers Jeremy Bentham and John Stuart Mill. In microeconomics, the utility maximization problem is the problem consumers face: "How should I spend my money in order to maximize my uti ...
,
profit maximization
In economics, profit maximization is the short run or long run process by which a firm may determine the price, input and output levels that will lead to the highest possible total profit (or just profit in short). In neoclassical economics, ...
, and
ideal type
Ideal type (), also known as pure type, is a typological term most closely associated with the sociologist Max Weber (1864–1920). For Weber, the conduct of social science depends upon the construction of abstract, hypothetical concepts. The "id ...
s—not merely to ''describe'' (which may be beside the point) but to ''predict'' economic behavior and to provide an engine of analysis (pp. 30–35).
On profit maximization, for example, firms are posited to push each line of action to the point of equating the relevant
marginal revenue
Marginal revenue (or marginal benefit) is a central concept in microeconomics that describes the additional total revenue generated by increasing product sales by 1 unit.Bradley R. chiller, "Essentials of Economics", New York: McGraw-Hill, Inc., ...
and
marginal cost
In economics, the marginal cost is the change in the total cost that arises when the quantity produced is increased, i.e. the cost of producing additional quantity. In some contexts, it refers to an increment of one unit of output, and in others it ...
. Yet, answers of businessmen to questions about the factors affecting their decisions may show no such calculation. Still, if firms act ''as if'' they are trying to maximize profits, that is the relevant test of the associated hypothesis (pp. 15, 22, 31).
Place in economic methodology
Friedman is acknowledged as a pivotal figure in the
Chicago school of economics
The Chicago school of economics is a Neoclassical economics, neoclassical Schools of economic thought, school of economic thought associated with the work of the faculty at the University of Chicago, some of whom have constructed and populari ...
. The essay can be read as a manifesto for that school. Still, Melvin Reder writes that a significant minority of Chicago-school economists such as
Ronald Coase
Ronald Harry Coase (; 29 December 1910 – 2 September 2013) was a British economist and author. Coase was educated at the London School of Economics, where he was a member of the faculty until 1951. He was the Clifton R. Musser Professor of Eco ...
and
James M. Buchanan have written as if "the validity of an economic theory lies in its intuitive appeal and/or its compatibility with a set of common-sense axioms rather than the conformity of its implications with empirical observation." Friedman's criterion of ''fruitfulness'' and usage of 'positive', however, seem to blur this point.
The essay's core claim and representation were by the late 1980s widely deployed in
mainstream economics
Mainstream economics is the body of knowledge, theories, and models of economics, as taught by universities worldwide, that are generally accepted by economists as a basis for discussion. Also known as orthodox economics, it can be contrasted to ...
, even if methodological judgments, like other regulative judgments, are not purely positive. Its critics however, had by then long pointed out the flaw in Friedman's reasoning: by shielding assumptions from the requirement of realism, Friedman admits falsehoods as part of his theory. He defends against this by requiring only certain phenomena of interest to be explained, but as Samuelson pointed out, this can lead to unscientific cherry-picking of results. Samuelson dubbed Friedman's principle the F-Twist, avoiding naming it after Friedman directly out of courtesy.
Daniel M. Hausman described "The Methodology of Positive Economics" as "the most influential work on economic methodology of
he twentiethcentury." He later noted that its influence was waning due to an empirical turn in economics that took place at the end the century, although by 2012 it still commonly served "as a way of avoiding awkward questions concerning simplifications, idealizations, and abstraction in economics rather than responding to them."
[Hausman 2012.]
Notes
References
* Milton Friedman, 1953. ''Essays in Positive Economics'', Chicago
Descriptionan
preview including "The Methodology...," pp. 3–43].
*
Lawrence A. Boland, 1987. “methodology," ''
The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics'', v. 3, 455–58
* _____, 2008. "assumptions controversy," ''
The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics
''The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics'' (2018), 3rd ed., is a twenty-volume reference work on economics published by Palgrave Macmillan. It contains around 3,000 entries, including many classic essays from the original Inglis Palgrave Dictio ...
'', 2nd Edition
Abstract.* _____, 2008. "instrumentalism and operationalism," ''The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics'', 2nd Edition.
Abstract.* Bruce Caldwell, 1980a. "Positivist Philosophy of Science and the Methodology of Economics," ''Journal of Economic Issues'', 14(1), pp
53–76
* _____, 1980a. "A Critique of Friedman's Methodological Instrumentalism," ''Southern Economic Journal'', 47(2), pp
366–74
* A. Coddington, 1972. "Positive Economics," ''Canadian Journal of Economics,'' 5(1), pp
1–15
* William J. Frazer Jr. and Lawrence A. Boland, 1983. "An Essay on the Foundations of Friedman's Methodology," ''American Economic Review'', 73(1), pp
129–44 Reprinted in J.C. Wood & R.N. Woods, ed., ''Milton Friedman: Critical Assessments'', v. III, pp
458–79
*
Daniel M. Hausman, ed., 2007. ''The Philosophy of Economics: An Anthology'', 3rd ed.
* Daniel M. Hausman, 2012.
Philosophy of Economics" in Edward N. Zalta, ed., ''
The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy
The ''Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy'' (''SEP'') is a freely available online philosophy resource published and maintained by Stanford University, encompassing both an online encyclopedia of philosophy and peer-reviewed original publication ...
''.
*
Kevin D. Hoover, 2009. "The Methodology of Causal Realism," in
Uskali Mäki Ismo Uskali Mäki (born 8 February 1951 Helsinki) is a Finnish professor in the Department of Political and Economic Studies (Philosophy) at the University of Helsinki
The University of Helsinki (, ; UH) is a public university in Helsinki, Fin ...
, ed., ''The Methodology of Positive Economics: Reflections on the Milton Friedman Legacy'', Cambridge, pp
303–20
*
Richard G. Lipsey, 200). "positive economics." ''The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics'', 2nd Edition
Abstract.*
Thomas Mayer, 1993. "Friedman's Methodology of Positive Economics: A Soft Reading," ''Economic Inquiry'', 31(2), pp. 213–23
Abstract
* M.W. Reder, 1987. “Chicago School," ''The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics'', v. 1, 41318.
* Eugene Rotwein, 1959. "On 'The Methodology of Positive Economics'," ''Quarterly Journal of Economics'',73(4), pp
554–75
*
Paul A. Samuelson, 1963. "Problems of Methodology: Discussion," ''American Economic Review'', 53(2) ''American Economic Review''
pp. 231–36 Reprinted in J.C. Wood and R.N. Woods, ed., 1990, ''Milton Friedman: Critical Assessments'', v. I. pp. 107–13
Preview.Routledge.
* A. Walters, 1987. "Friedman, Milton," ''The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics'', v. 2, 422–26.
* Stanley Wong, 1973. "The 'F-Twist' and the Methodology of Paul Samuelson," ''American Economic Review'', 63(3)
pp. 312–25 Reprinted in J.C. Wood & R.N. Woods, ed., 1990, ''Milton Friedman: Critical Assessments'', v. II, pp.
224–43
* _____, 1987. “positive economics," ''The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics'', v. 3, 920–21.
External links
* ____, 1966
"The Methodology of Positive Economics,"pp. 3–16, 30–43
of Nobel prize lecture with pp. 1–2 on econ. methodology & the rest as example.
{{Milton Friedman
1953 non-fiction books
Works by Milton Friedman
University of Chicago Press books
Essay collections
Works about philosophy of economics