Discrete Fixed-point Theorem
   HOME

TheInfoList



OR:

In
discrete mathematics Discrete mathematics is the study of mathematical structures that can be considered "discrete" (in a way analogous to discrete variables, having a bijection with the set of natural numbers) rather than "continuous" (analogously to continuous f ...
, a discrete fixed-point is a fixed-point for functions defined on finite sets, typically subsets of the integer grid \mathbb^n. Discrete fixed-point theorems were developed by Iimura, Murota and Tamura, Chen and Deng and others. Yang provides a survey.


Basic concepts

Continuous fixed-point theorems often require a
continuous function In mathematics, a continuous function is a function such that a small variation of the argument induces a small variation of the value of the function. This implies there are no abrupt changes in value, known as '' discontinuities''. More preci ...
. Since continuity is not meaningful for functions on discrete sets, it is replaced by conditions such as a
direction-preserving function In discrete mathematics, a direction-preserving function (or mapping) is a function on a discrete space, such as the integer grid, that (informally) does not change too drastically between two adjacent points. It can be considered a discrete analogu ...
. Such conditions imply that the function does not change too drastically when moving between neighboring points of the integer grid. There are various direction-preservation conditions, depending on whether neighboring points are considered points of a hypercube (HGDP), of a simplex (SGDP) etc. See the page on
direction-preserving function In discrete mathematics, a direction-preserving function (or mapping) is a function on a discrete space, such as the integer grid, that (informally) does not change too drastically between two adjacent points. It can be considered a discrete analogu ...
for definitions. Continuous fixed-point theorems often require a
convex set In geometry, a set of points is convex if it contains every line segment between two points in the set. For example, a solid cube (geometry), cube is a convex set, but anything that is hollow or has an indent, for example, a crescent shape, is n ...
. The analogue of this property for discrete sets is an integrally-convex set. A fixed point of a discrete function ''f'' is defined exactly as for continuous functions: it is a point ''x'' for which ''f''(''x'')=''x''.


For functions on discrete sets

We focus on functions f: X\to \mathbb^n, where the domain X is a nonempty subset of the Euclidean space \mathbb^n. ch(''X'') denotes the
convex hull In geometry, the convex hull, convex envelope or convex closure of a shape is the smallest convex set that contains it. The convex hull may be defined either as the intersection of all convex sets containing a given subset of a Euclidean space, ...
of ''X''. Iimura-Murota-Tamura theorem: If ''X'' is a finite integrally-convex subset of \mathbb^n, and f: X\to \text(X) is a ''hypercubic direction-preserving (HDP)'' function, then ''f'' has a fixed-point. Chen-Deng theorem: If ''X'' is a finite subset of \mathbb^n, and f: X\to \text(X) is ''simplicially direction-preserving'' ''(SDP)'', then ''f'' has a fixed-point. Yang's theorems: * .6 If ''X'' is a finite integrally-convex subset of \mathbb^n, f: X\to \mathbb^n is ''simplicially gross direction preserving (SGDP)'', and for all ''x'' in ''X'' there exists some ''g''(''x'')>0 such that x+g(x)f(x)\in \text(X), then ''f'' has a zero point. * .7 If ''X'' is a finite hypercubic subset of \mathbb^n, with minimum point ''a'' and maximum point ''b'', f: X\to \mathbb^n is SGDP, and for any ''x'' in ''X'': f_i(x_1,\ldots,x_,a_i,x_,\ldots,x_n) \leq 0 and f_i(x_1,\ldots,x_,b_i,x_,\ldots,x_n) \geq 0, then ''f'' has a zero point. This is a discrete analogue of the Poincaré–Miranda theorem. It is a consequence of the previous theorem. * .8 If ''X'' is a finite integrally-convex subset of \mathbb^n, and f: X\to \text(X) is such that f(x)-x is ''SGDP'', then ''f'' has a fixed-point. This is a discrete analogue of the
Brouwer fixed-point theorem Brouwer's fixed-point theorem is a fixed-point theorem in topology, named after Luitzen Egbertus Jan Brouwer, L. E. J. (Bertus) Brouwer. It states that for any continuous function f mapping a nonempty compactness, compact convex set to itself, the ...
. * .9 If X = \mathbb^n, f: X\to \mathbb^n is bounded and f(x)-x is SGDP, then ''f'' has a fixed-point (this follows easily from the previous theorem by taking ''X'' to be a subset of \mathbb^n that bounds ''f''). * .10If ''X'' is a finite integrally-convex subset of \mathbb^n, F: X\to 2^X a point-to-set mapping, and for all ''x'' in ''X'': F(x) = \text(F(x))\cap \mathbb^n , and there is a function ''f'' such that f(x)\in \text(F(x)) and f(x)-x is SGDP, then there is a point ''y'' in ''X'' such that y \in F(y). This is a discrete analogue of the
Kakutani fixed-point theorem In mathematical analysis, the Kakutani fixed-point theorem is a fixed-point theorem for set-valued functions. It provides sufficient conditions for a set-valued function defined on a convex, compact subset of a Euclidean space to have a fixed poi ...
, and the function ''f'' is an analogue of a continuous selection function. * .12Suppose ''X'' is a finite integrally-convex subset of \mathbb^n, and it is also ''symmetric'' in the sense that ''x'' is in ''X'' iff -''x'' is in ''X''. If f: X\to \mathbb^n is SGDP w.r.t. a ''weakly-symmetric'' triangulation of ch(''X'') (in the sense that if ''s'' is a simplex on the boundary of the triangulation iff -''s'' is), and f(x)\cdot f(-y) \leq 0 for every pair of simplicially-connected points ''x'', ''y'' in the boundary of ch(''X''), then ''f'' has a zero point. *See the survey for more theorems. *


For discontinuous functions on continuous sets

Discrete fixed-point theorems are closely related to fixed-point theorems on discontinuous functions. These, too, use the direction-preservation condition instead of continuity. Herings-Laan-Talman-Yang fixed-point theorem: Let ''X'' be a non-empty convex compact subset of \mathbb^n. Let ''f'': ''X'' → ''X'' be a ''locally gross direction preserving (LGDP)'' function: at any point ''x'' that is not a fixed point of ''f'', the direction of f(x)-x is grossly preserved in some
neighborhood A neighbourhood (Commonwealth English) or neighborhood (American English) is a geographically localized community within a larger town, city, suburb or rural area, sometimes consisting of a single street and the buildings lining it. Neigh ...
of ''x'', in the sense that for any two points ''y'', ''z'' in this neighborhood, its inner product is non-negative, i.e.: (f(y)-y)\cdot (f(z)-z) \geq 0. Then ''f'' has a fixed point in ''X''. The theorem is originally stated for polytopes, but Philippe Bich extends it to convex compact sets.Note that every
continuous function In mathematics, a continuous function is a function such that a small variation of the argument induces a small variation of the value of the function. This implies there are no abrupt changes in value, known as '' discontinuities''. More preci ...
is LGDP, but an LGDP function may be discontinuous. An LGDP function may even be neither upper nor lower semi-continuous. Moreover, there is a constructive algorithm for approximating this fixed point.


Applications

Discrete fixed-point theorems have been used to prove the existence of a
Nash equilibrium In game theory, the Nash equilibrium is the most commonly used solution concept for non-cooperative games. A Nash equilibrium is a situation where no player could gain by changing their own strategy (holding all other players' strategies fixed) ...
in a discrete game, and the existence of a
Walrasian equilibrium Competitive equilibrium (also called: Walrasian equilibrium) is a concept of economic equilibrium, introduced by Kenneth Arrow and Gérard Debreu in 1951, appropriate for the analysis of commodity markets with flexible prices and many traders, and ...
in a discrete market.


References

{{reflist Discrete mathematics Fixed-point theorems