
Adjusted Winner (AW) is an algorithm for
envy-free item allocation
Envy-free (EF) item allocation is a fair item allocation problem, in which the fairness criterion is envy-freeness - each agent should receive a bundle that they believe to be at least as good as the bundle of any other agent.
Since the items are ...
. Given two parties and some discrete goods, it returns a partition of the goods between the two parties that is:
#
Envy-free
Envy-freeness, also known as no-envy, is a criterion for fair division. It says that, when resources are allocated among people with equal rights, each person should receive a share that is, in their eyes, at least as good as the share received by ...
: Each party believes their share of the goods is as good as or better than their opponent's;
#
Equitable: The "relative happiness levels" of both parties from their shares are equal;
#
Pareto-optimal: no other allocation is better for one party and still at least as good for the other party; and
# Involves splitting at most one good between the parties.
It is the only procedure that can satisfy all four properties simultaneously.
Despite this, however, there are no accounts of the algorithm actually being used to resolve disputes.
The procedure was designed by
Steven Brams
Steven J. Brams (born November 28, 1940) is an American game theorist and political scientist at the New York University Department of Politics. Brams is best known for using the techniques of game theory, public choice theory, and social choice ...
and
Alan D. Taylor, and published in their book on fair division
and later in a stand-alone book.
Adjusted Winning was previously patented in the United States, but expired in 2016.
[, ''Computer-based method for the fair division of ownership of goods''.]
Algorithm
Each party is given the list of goods and an equal, fixed number of points to distribute among them. They then assign values to each good and submit their (sealed) list of bids to an arbiter, who assigns each item to its highest bidder.
If the combined value of one party's goods are then greater than the other's, the algorithm then orders the higher-valued-party's goods in increasing order based on the ratio
and begins transferring them from the higher-combined value party to the lower-combined value party until their valuations are almost equal (moving any more goods would cause the lower-combined-value party to now have a higher combined value than the other). The next good is then divided between the parties such that their values become the same.
As an example, if two parties have the following valuations for four goods:
* Alice: 86, 75, 30, 9
* Bob: 19, 81, 60, 40
The goods would first be divided such that Alice receives good 1, while Bob receives goods 2, 3, and 4. At this point, Alice's combined valuation of her goods is 86, while Bob's is 81 + 60 + 40 = 181; as such, Bob's goods are then ordered based on the ratio
, giving
*
\frac">ood 2 = \frac">ood 3 = \frac">ood 4 =
Moving Good 2 from Bob to Alice would cause Alice to have a valuation greater than Bob's (161 versus 100), so no goods are transferred. Instead, Good 2 is split between Alice and Bob: Alice receives
th of the good (approximately 60.9%), while Bob receives
th (approximately 39.1%). Their valuations now become
and
respectively, which are equal.
Simulations
There are no cases of Adjusted Winner being used to resolve real-life disputes. However, some studies have simulated how certain disputes would have resulted had the algorithm been used, including
* the
Camp David Accords
The Camp David Accords were a pair of political agreements signed by Egyptian president Anwar Sadat and Israeli prime minister Menachem Begin on 17 September 1978, following twelve days of secret negotiations at Camp David, the country retre ...
, whose valuation functions were modelled on the relative importance of each issue for Israel and Egypt, and whose theoretical results were similar to the actual agreement;
* For the
Israeli–Palestinian conflict
The Israeli–Palestinian conflict is an ongoing military and political conflict about Territory, land and self-determination within the territory of the former Mandatory Palestine. Key aspects of the conflict include the Israeli occupation ...
;
* For the
Spratly Islands dispute;
* the
Panama Canal Treaties
Panama, officially the Republic of Panama, is a country in Latin America at the southern end of Central America, bordering South America. It is bordered by Costa Rica to the west, Colombia to the southeast, the Caribbean Sea to the north, and ...
; and
* the 1980 ''Jolis v. Jolis'' divorce case.
Limitations
AW is not a
truthful mechanism
In mechanism design, a strategyproof (SP) mechanism is a game form in which each player has a weakly- dominant strategy, so that no player can gain by "spying" over the other players to know what they are going to play. When the players have privat ...
: a party can gain from spying on its opponent and modifying their reports in order to get a larger share.
However, Adjusted Winner always has an approximate
Nash equilibrium
In game theory, the Nash equilibrium is the most commonly used solution concept for non-cooperative games. A Nash equilibrium is a situation where no player could gain by changing their own strategy (holding all other players' strategies fixed) ...
, and under informed tie-breaking, also a pure Nash equilibrium.
As patented, the algorithm assumes the parties have
additive utility functions: the value of their goods is equal to the sum of the individual goods' values. It does not handle, for example, multiple instances of a good with
diminishing marginal utilities.
The algorithm also is designed for two parties only; when there are three or more parties, there may be no allocation that is simultaneously envy-free, equitable, and Pareto-optimal. This can be shown by the following example, constructed by J.H.Reijnierse,
involving three parties and their valuations:
* Alice: 40, 50, 10
* Bob: 30, 40, 30
* Carl: 30, 30, 40
The only Pareto-optimal and equitable allocation would be the one giving good 1 to Alice, good 2 to Bob, and good 3 to Carl; however, this allocation would not be envy-free since Alice would envy Bob.
Any two of these three properties can be satisfied simultaneously:
* An envy-free and equitable allocation could be found by giving each party an equal amount of each good.
* An envy-free and Pareto-optimal allocation could be found via
Pareto-efficient envy-free division or
Weller's theorem Weller's theorem is a theorem in economics. It says that a heterogeneous resource ("cake") can be divided among ''n'' partners with different valuations in a way that is both Pareto-efficient (PE) and envy-free (EF). Thus, it is possible to divide a ...
.
* An equitable and Pareto-optimal allocation could be found via
linear programming
Linear programming (LP), also called linear optimization, is a method to achieve the best outcome (such as maximum profit or lowest cost) in a mathematical model whose requirements and objective are represented by linear function#As a polynomia ...
.
Moreover, it is possible to find an allocation that, while being Pareto-optimal/envy-free or Pareto-optimal/equitable, would minimize the number of objects that have to be shared between two or more parties. This it usually considered the generalization of the Adjusted Winner procedure to three or more parties.
Adjusted Winner is designed for agents with positive valuations over the items. It can be generalized for parties with mixed (positive and negative) valuations, however.
Related procedures
The
Brams–Taylor procedure was designed by the same authors, but it is instead a procedure for
envy-free cake-cutting
An envy-free cake-cutting is a kind of fair cake-cutting. It is a division of a heterogeneous resource ("cake") that satisfies the envy-free criterion, namely, that every partner feels that their allocated share is at least as good as any other sh ...
: it handles heterogeneous resources ("cake") which are more challenging to divide than Adjusted Winning's homogeneous goods. Accordingly, BT guarantees only envy-freeness, not any other attributes.
The article on
Fair division experiments describes some laboratory experiments comparing AW to related procedures.
References
External links
Website explaining Adjusted Winner
{{DEFAULTSORT:Adjusted Winner Procedure
Fair division protocols
Dispute resolution